Card rewards: is there a 'Reverse-Robin-Hood-Effect'?
The main argument against interchange fees has always been that they are an anticompetitive instrument to raise the costs of card acceptance. In turn, high costs of card acceptance would lead to high retail prices harming consumers. Schuh, Scott, Oz Shy, and Joanna Stavins (2010) have added a new di...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Banking & Financial Services Policy Report 2015-03, Vol.34 (3), p.20 |
---|---|
1. Verfasser: | |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | |
---|---|
container_issue | 3 |
container_start_page | 20 |
container_title | Banking & Financial Services Policy Report |
container_volume | 34 |
creator | Krueger, Malte |
description | The main argument against interchange fees has always been that they are an anticompetitive instrument to raise the costs of card acceptance. In turn, high costs of card acceptance would lead to high retail prices harming consumers. Schuh, Scott, Oz Shy, and Joanna Stavins (2010) have added a new dimension to this critical view of interchange fees. One of the authors has dubbed this distributional effect as "Reverse-Robin-Hood-Cross- Subsidy." The main cause of this effect is the interaction of interchange fees and reward programs. Therefore, a model of product differentiation is used in this discussion to show that it may be much more difficult than is commonly assumed to estimate such distributional effects and that card users may, in fact, pay a large portion of their rewards themselves. This result is based on a form of "implicit surcharging." If merchants practice such implicit surcharging, they may recover card costs from card users without resorting to an explicit surcharge. |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>gale_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_reports_1667368172</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><galeid>A407109857</galeid><sourcerecordid>A407109857</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-g1022-785a5e9f5ef95ec2c7bd1db3c73239b220c6c8e7b281cee90b1e0b7f5d188be23</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNpNzMFLwzAYBfAeFJzT_6F42cVAkjZN4kVGmU4YCEPBW0nSL12lNDNfqv--lXnY5T14_HgX2YKJgpJS64-r7Brxk1KqSl0tMlGb2OYRfubCh7zHPB0gQm7y1R6-ISKQfbD9SLYhtGTjPbi0erzJLr0ZEG7_e5m9P23e6i3ZvT6_1Osd6RjlnEgljADtBXgtwHEnbctaWzhZ8EJbzqmrnAJpuWIOQFPLgFrpRcuUssCLZXZ3-j3G8DUBpibCMcSEDasqWVSKyT9ETqgzAzT96EOKxnUwQjRDGMH387wuqWRUKyFnf3_m7YT9CDgH9t0hYWcmxHP-C-RiXeo</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1667368172</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Card rewards: is there a 'Reverse-Robin-Hood-Effect'?</title><source>Business Source Complete</source><creator>Krueger, Malte</creator><creatorcontrib>Krueger, Malte</creatorcontrib><description>The main argument against interchange fees has always been that they are an anticompetitive instrument to raise the costs of card acceptance. In turn, high costs of card acceptance would lead to high retail prices harming consumers. Schuh, Scott, Oz Shy, and Joanna Stavins (2010) have added a new dimension to this critical view of interchange fees. One of the authors has dubbed this distributional effect as "Reverse-Robin-Hood-Cross- Subsidy." The main cause of this effect is the interaction of interchange fees and reward programs. Therefore, a model of product differentiation is used in this discussion to show that it may be much more difficult than is commonly assumed to estimate such distributional effects and that card users may, in fact, pay a large portion of their rewards themselves. This result is based on a form of "implicit surcharging." If merchants practice such implicit surcharging, they may recover card costs from card users without resorting to an explicit surcharge.</description><identifier>ISSN: 1530-499X</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Gaithersburg: Aspen Publishers, Inc</publisher><subject>Consumers ; Costs ; Costs (Law) ; Credit card industry ; Customers ; High income ; Households ; Interchange rates ; Low income groups ; Loyalty programs ; Prices ; Pricing policies ; Product acceptance ; Product differentiation ; Studies ; Subsidies ; Surcharges ; Willingness to pay</subject><ispartof>Banking & Financial Services Policy Report, 2015-03, Vol.34 (3), p.20</ispartof><rights>COPYRIGHT 2015 Aspen Publishers, Inc.</rights><rights>Copyright Aspen Publishers, Inc. Mar 2015</rights><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><link.rule.ids>312,314,777,781,788</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Krueger, Malte</creatorcontrib><title>Card rewards: is there a 'Reverse-Robin-Hood-Effect'?</title><title>Banking & Financial Services Policy Report</title><description>The main argument against interchange fees has always been that they are an anticompetitive instrument to raise the costs of card acceptance. In turn, high costs of card acceptance would lead to high retail prices harming consumers. Schuh, Scott, Oz Shy, and Joanna Stavins (2010) have added a new dimension to this critical view of interchange fees. One of the authors has dubbed this distributional effect as "Reverse-Robin-Hood-Cross- Subsidy." The main cause of this effect is the interaction of interchange fees and reward programs. Therefore, a model of product differentiation is used in this discussion to show that it may be much more difficult than is commonly assumed to estimate such distributional effects and that card users may, in fact, pay a large portion of their rewards themselves. This result is based on a form of "implicit surcharging." If merchants practice such implicit surcharging, they may recover card costs from card users without resorting to an explicit surcharge.</description><subject>Consumers</subject><subject>Costs</subject><subject>Costs (Law)</subject><subject>Credit card industry</subject><subject>Customers</subject><subject>High income</subject><subject>Households</subject><subject>Interchange rates</subject><subject>Low income groups</subject><subject>Loyalty programs</subject><subject>Prices</subject><subject>Pricing policies</subject><subject>Product acceptance</subject><subject>Product differentiation</subject><subject>Studies</subject><subject>Subsidies</subject><subject>Surcharges</subject><subject>Willingness to pay</subject><issn>1530-499X</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2015</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>N95</sourceid><sourceid>AFKRA</sourceid><sourceid>BENPR</sourceid><sourceid>CCPQU</sourceid><sourceid>DWQXO</sourceid><recordid>eNpNzMFLwzAYBfAeFJzT_6F42cVAkjZN4kVGmU4YCEPBW0nSL12lNDNfqv--lXnY5T14_HgX2YKJgpJS64-r7Brxk1KqSl0tMlGb2OYRfubCh7zHPB0gQm7y1R6-ISKQfbD9SLYhtGTjPbi0erzJLr0ZEG7_e5m9P23e6i3ZvT6_1Osd6RjlnEgljADtBXgtwHEnbctaWzhZ8EJbzqmrnAJpuWIOQFPLgFrpRcuUssCLZXZ3-j3G8DUBpibCMcSEDasqWVSKyT9ETqgzAzT96EOKxnUwQjRDGMH387wuqWRUKyFnf3_m7YT9CDgH9t0hYWcmxHP-C-RiXeo</recordid><startdate>20150301</startdate><enddate>20150301</enddate><creator>Krueger, Malte</creator><general>Aspen Publishers, Inc</general><scope>N95</scope><scope>XI7</scope><scope>7XB</scope><scope>AFKRA</scope><scope>ANIOZ</scope><scope>BENPR</scope><scope>BEZIV</scope><scope>CCPQU</scope><scope>DWQXO</scope><scope>K6~</scope><scope>M1F</scope><scope>PQBIZ</scope><scope>PQEST</scope><scope>PQQKQ</scope><scope>PQUKI</scope><scope>Q9U</scope><scope>S0X</scope></search><sort><creationdate>20150301</creationdate><title>Card rewards: is there a 'Reverse-Robin-Hood-Effect'?</title><author>Krueger, Malte</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-g1022-785a5e9f5ef95ec2c7bd1db3c73239b220c6c8e7b281cee90b1e0b7f5d188be23</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2015</creationdate><topic>Consumers</topic><topic>Costs</topic><topic>Costs (Law)</topic><topic>Credit card industry</topic><topic>Customers</topic><topic>High income</topic><topic>Households</topic><topic>Interchange rates</topic><topic>Low income groups</topic><topic>Loyalty programs</topic><topic>Prices</topic><topic>Pricing policies</topic><topic>Product acceptance</topic><topic>Product differentiation</topic><topic>Studies</topic><topic>Subsidies</topic><topic>Surcharges</topic><topic>Willingness to pay</topic><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Krueger, Malte</creatorcontrib><collection>Gale Business: Insights</collection><collection>Business Insights: Essentials</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central UK/Ireland</collection><collection>Accounting, Tax & Banking Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest One Community College</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Korea</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection</collection><collection>Banking Information Database</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic Eastern Edition (DO NOT USE)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic UKI Edition</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Basic</collection><collection>SIRS Editorial</collection><jtitle>Banking & Financial Services Policy Report</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Krueger, Malte</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Card rewards: is there a 'Reverse-Robin-Hood-Effect'?</atitle><jtitle>Banking & Financial Services Policy Report</jtitle><date>2015-03-01</date><risdate>2015</risdate><volume>34</volume><issue>3</issue><spage>20</spage><pages>20-</pages><issn>1530-499X</issn><abstract>The main argument against interchange fees has always been that they are an anticompetitive instrument to raise the costs of card acceptance. In turn, high costs of card acceptance would lead to high retail prices harming consumers. Schuh, Scott, Oz Shy, and Joanna Stavins (2010) have added a new dimension to this critical view of interchange fees. One of the authors has dubbed this distributional effect as "Reverse-Robin-Hood-Cross- Subsidy." The main cause of this effect is the interaction of interchange fees and reward programs. Therefore, a model of product differentiation is used in this discussion to show that it may be much more difficult than is commonly assumed to estimate such distributional effects and that card users may, in fact, pay a large portion of their rewards themselves. This result is based on a form of "implicit surcharging." If merchants practice such implicit surcharging, they may recover card costs from card users without resorting to an explicit surcharge.</abstract><cop>Gaithersburg</cop><pub>Aspen Publishers, Inc</pub></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 1530-499X |
ispartof | Banking & Financial Services Policy Report, 2015-03, Vol.34 (3), p.20 |
issn | 1530-499X |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_reports_1667368172 |
source | Business Source Complete |
subjects | Consumers Costs Costs (Law) Credit card industry Customers High income Households Interchange rates Low income groups Loyalty programs Prices Pricing policies Product acceptance Product differentiation Studies Subsidies Surcharges Willingness to pay |
title | Card rewards: is there a 'Reverse-Robin-Hood-Effect'? |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-17T10%3A38%3A40IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-gale_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Card%20rewards:%20is%20there%20a%20'Reverse-Robin-Hood-Effect'?&rft.jtitle=Banking%20&%20Financial%20Services%20Policy%20Report&rft.au=Krueger,%20Malte&rft.date=2015-03-01&rft.volume=34&rft.issue=3&rft.spage=20&rft.pages=20-&rft.issn=1530-499X&rft_id=info:doi/&rft_dat=%3Cgale_proqu%3EA407109857%3C/gale_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1667368172&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_galeid=A407109857&rfr_iscdi=true |