The Nonpecuniary Costs of Accidents: Pain-and-Suffering Damages in Tort Law
Conventional wisdom holds that tort awards for nonpecuniary losses are undesirable from an insurance standpoint. Professors Croley and Hanson challenge this wisdom. After providing a critique of several reform proposals predicated on that wisdom and explaining why rational consumers might well deman...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Harvard law review 1995-06, Vol.108 (8), p.1785-1917 |
---|---|
Hauptverfasser: | , |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 1917 |
---|---|
container_issue | 8 |
container_start_page | 1785 |
container_title | Harvard law review |
container_volume | 108 |
creator | Croley, Steven P. Hanson, Jon D. |
description | Conventional wisdom holds that tort awards for nonpecuniary losses are undesirable from an insurance standpoint. Professors Croley and Hanson challenge this wisdom. After providing a critique of several reform proposals predicated on that wisdom and explaining why rational consumers might well demand insurance against nonpecuniary losses, they argue that the empirical evidence upon which the conventional wisdom is largely based is more complicated than previously recognized. In particular, several market impediments seriously limit the extent to which inferences about consumer demand can be drawn from looking solely to first-party insurance markets. With those impediments in mind, however, one can see more clearly the modest market evidence of such demand. Moreover, certain nonmarket evidence further suggests that consumers may demand insurance against nonpecuniary losses, though the market's ability to answer that demand is limited. The tort system, in contrast, has several advantages that may render it a superior institution for providing nonpecuniary-loss insurance. |
doi_str_mv | 10.2307/1341946 |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>jstor_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_61173704</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><jstor_id>1341946</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>1341946</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c396t-d7b5cac6c306594e4d7183ba0c7f48f31f4fd4105e8df608c996fff086b1a6093</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqF0V9LIzEUBfAgLlh18SsEFX0avTfJJBnfpOs_tujCVvBtSDOJTmmTmswg--13pH0SpE_35ceFcw4hRwgXjIO6RC6wEnKHjBhKLColX3bJCABVoRFf9sh-znMAkFyJEfk9fXP0MYaVs31oTfpHxzF3mUZPr61tGxe6fEX_mDYUJjTF3957l9rwSn-ZpXl1mbaBTmPq6MR8HJIf3iyy-7m5B-T59mY6vi8mT3cP4-tJYXklu6JRs9IaKy0HWVbCiUah5jMDVnmhPUcvfCMQSqcbL0HbqpLee9ByhkZCxQ_I2frvKsX33uWuXrbZusXCBBf7XEtExRWIrZBrraHkbIDHX-A89ikMIWqGWgtWatiGkDPQAzr5DiGrgGkm1GeC87WyKeacnK9XqV0O7dcI9eeK9WbFQZ6u5Tx3MX3L_gOPGJYN</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1290282479</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>The Nonpecuniary Costs of Accidents: Pain-and-Suffering Damages in Tort Law</title><source>Jstor Complete Legacy</source><source>PAIS Index</source><source>Worldwide Political Science Abstracts</source><source>HeinOnline Law Journal Library</source><source>Business Source Complete</source><source>Periodicals Index Online</source><creator>Croley, Steven P. ; Hanson, Jon D.</creator><creatorcontrib>Croley, Steven P. ; Hanson, Jon D.</creatorcontrib><description>Conventional wisdom holds that tort awards for nonpecuniary losses are undesirable from an insurance standpoint. Professors Croley and Hanson challenge this wisdom. After providing a critique of several reform proposals predicated on that wisdom and explaining why rational consumers might well demand insurance against nonpecuniary losses, they argue that the empirical evidence upon which the conventional wisdom is largely based is more complicated than previously recognized. In particular, several market impediments seriously limit the extent to which inferences about consumer demand can be drawn from looking solely to first-party insurance markets. With those impediments in mind, however, one can see more clearly the modest market evidence of such demand. Moreover, certain nonmarket evidence further suggests that consumers may demand insurance against nonpecuniary losses, though the market's ability to answer that demand is limited. The tort system, in contrast, has several advantages that may render it a superior institution for providing nonpecuniary-loss insurance.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0017-811X</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 2161-976X</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.2307/1341946</identifier><identifier>CODEN: HALRAF</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Cambridge: Harvard Law Review Association</publisher><subject>Accidents ; Civil proceedings ; Compensation ; Consumer demand ; Consumer economics ; Health insurance ; Insurance coverage ; Insurance policies ; Insurance providers ; Juries ; Labour law ; Law ; Legal reform ; Liability ; Liability insurance ; Life insurance ; Pain and suffering ; Settlements & damages ; State court decisions ; Torts ; U.S.A ; United States ; Work accidents</subject><ispartof>Harvard law review, 1995-06, Vol.108 (8), p.1785-1917</ispartof><rights>Copyright 1995 The Harvard Law Review Association</rights><rights>Copyright Harvard Law Review Association Jun 1995</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c396t-d7b5cac6c306594e4d7183ba0c7f48f31f4fd4105e8df608c996fff086b1a6093</citedby></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/1341946$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/1341946$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,776,780,799,27843,27846,27901,27902,57992,58225</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Croley, Steven P.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Hanson, Jon D.</creatorcontrib><title>The Nonpecuniary Costs of Accidents: Pain-and-Suffering Damages in Tort Law</title><title>Harvard law review</title><description>Conventional wisdom holds that tort awards for nonpecuniary losses are undesirable from an insurance standpoint. Professors Croley and Hanson challenge this wisdom. After providing a critique of several reform proposals predicated on that wisdom and explaining why rational consumers might well demand insurance against nonpecuniary losses, they argue that the empirical evidence upon which the conventional wisdom is largely based is more complicated than previously recognized. In particular, several market impediments seriously limit the extent to which inferences about consumer demand can be drawn from looking solely to first-party insurance markets. With those impediments in mind, however, one can see more clearly the modest market evidence of such demand. Moreover, certain nonmarket evidence further suggests that consumers may demand insurance against nonpecuniary losses, though the market's ability to answer that demand is limited. The tort system, in contrast, has several advantages that may render it a superior institution for providing nonpecuniary-loss insurance.</description><subject>Accidents</subject><subject>Civil proceedings</subject><subject>Compensation</subject><subject>Consumer demand</subject><subject>Consumer economics</subject><subject>Health insurance</subject><subject>Insurance coverage</subject><subject>Insurance policies</subject><subject>Insurance providers</subject><subject>Juries</subject><subject>Labour law</subject><subject>Law</subject><subject>Legal reform</subject><subject>Liability</subject><subject>Liability insurance</subject><subject>Life insurance</subject><subject>Pain and suffering</subject><subject>Settlements & damages</subject><subject>State court decisions</subject><subject>Torts</subject><subject>U.S.A</subject><subject>United States</subject><subject>Work accidents</subject><issn>0017-811X</issn><issn>2161-976X</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>1995</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>K30</sourceid><sourceid>7TQ</sourceid><sourceid>7UB</sourceid><recordid>eNqF0V9LIzEUBfAgLlh18SsEFX0avTfJJBnfpOs_tujCVvBtSDOJTmmTmswg--13pH0SpE_35ceFcw4hRwgXjIO6RC6wEnKHjBhKLColX3bJCABVoRFf9sh-znMAkFyJEfk9fXP0MYaVs31oTfpHxzF3mUZPr61tGxe6fEX_mDYUJjTF3957l9rwSn-ZpXl1mbaBTmPq6MR8HJIf3iyy-7m5B-T59mY6vi8mT3cP4-tJYXklu6JRs9IaKy0HWVbCiUah5jMDVnmhPUcvfCMQSqcbL0HbqpLee9ByhkZCxQ_I2frvKsX33uWuXrbZusXCBBf7XEtExRWIrZBrraHkbIDHX-A89ikMIWqGWgtWatiGkDPQAzr5DiGrgGkm1GeC87WyKeacnK9XqV0O7dcI9eeK9WbFQZ6u5Tx3MX3L_gOPGJYN</recordid><startdate>19950601</startdate><enddate>19950601</enddate><creator>Croley, Steven P.</creator><creator>Hanson, Jon D.</creator><general>Harvard Law Review Association</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>EOLOZ</scope><scope>FKUCP</scope><scope>IOIBA</scope><scope>K30</scope><scope>PAAUG</scope><scope>PAWHS</scope><scope>PAWZZ</scope><scope>PAXOH</scope><scope>PBHAV</scope><scope>PBQSW</scope><scope>PBYQZ</scope><scope>PCIWU</scope><scope>PCMID</scope><scope>PCZJX</scope><scope>PDGRG</scope><scope>PDWWI</scope><scope>PETMR</scope><scope>PFVGT</scope><scope>PGXDX</scope><scope>PIHIL</scope><scope>PISVA</scope><scope>PJCTQ</scope><scope>PJTMS</scope><scope>PLCHJ</scope><scope>PMHAD</scope><scope>PNQDJ</scope><scope>POUND</scope><scope>PPLAD</scope><scope>PQAPC</scope><scope>PQCAN</scope><scope>PQCMW</scope><scope>PQEME</scope><scope>PQHKH</scope><scope>PQMID</scope><scope>PQNCT</scope><scope>PQNET</scope><scope>PQSCT</scope><scope>PQSET</scope><scope>PSVJG</scope><scope>PVMQY</scope><scope>PZGFC</scope><scope>7TQ</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>DHY</scope><scope>DON</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope><scope>7UB</scope></search><sort><creationdate>19950601</creationdate><title>The Nonpecuniary Costs of Accidents: Pain-and-Suffering Damages in Tort Law</title><author>Croley, Steven P. ; Hanson, Jon D.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c396t-d7b5cac6c306594e4d7183ba0c7f48f31f4fd4105e8df608c996fff086b1a6093</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>1995</creationdate><topic>Accidents</topic><topic>Civil proceedings</topic><topic>Compensation</topic><topic>Consumer demand</topic><topic>Consumer economics</topic><topic>Health insurance</topic><topic>Insurance coverage</topic><topic>Insurance policies</topic><topic>Insurance providers</topic><topic>Juries</topic><topic>Labour law</topic><topic>Law</topic><topic>Legal reform</topic><topic>Liability</topic><topic>Liability insurance</topic><topic>Life insurance</topic><topic>Pain and suffering</topic><topic>Settlements & damages</topic><topic>State court decisions</topic><topic>Torts</topic><topic>U.S.A</topic><topic>United States</topic><topic>Work accidents</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Croley, Steven P.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Hanson, Jon D.</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 01</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 04</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 29</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - West</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segments 1-50</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - MEA</collection><collection>PAIS Index</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>PAIS International</collection><collection>PAIS International (Ovid)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>Worldwide Political Science Abstracts</collection><jtitle>Harvard law review</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Croley, Steven P.</au><au>Hanson, Jon D.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>The Nonpecuniary Costs of Accidents: Pain-and-Suffering Damages in Tort Law</atitle><jtitle>Harvard law review</jtitle><date>1995-06-01</date><risdate>1995</risdate><volume>108</volume><issue>8</issue><spage>1785</spage><epage>1917</epage><pages>1785-1917</pages><issn>0017-811X</issn><eissn>2161-976X</eissn><coden>HALRAF</coden><abstract>Conventional wisdom holds that tort awards for nonpecuniary losses are undesirable from an insurance standpoint. Professors Croley and Hanson challenge this wisdom. After providing a critique of several reform proposals predicated on that wisdom and explaining why rational consumers might well demand insurance against nonpecuniary losses, they argue that the empirical evidence upon which the conventional wisdom is largely based is more complicated than previously recognized. In particular, several market impediments seriously limit the extent to which inferences about consumer demand can be drawn from looking solely to first-party insurance markets. With those impediments in mind, however, one can see more clearly the modest market evidence of such demand. Moreover, certain nonmarket evidence further suggests that consumers may demand insurance against nonpecuniary losses, though the market's ability to answer that demand is limited. The tort system, in contrast, has several advantages that may render it a superior institution for providing nonpecuniary-loss insurance.</abstract><cop>Cambridge</cop><pub>Harvard Law Review Association</pub><doi>10.2307/1341946</doi><tpages>133</tpages></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0017-811X |
ispartof | Harvard law review, 1995-06, Vol.108 (8), p.1785-1917 |
issn | 0017-811X 2161-976X |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_61173704 |
source | Jstor Complete Legacy; PAIS Index; Worldwide Political Science Abstracts; HeinOnline Law Journal Library; Business Source Complete; Periodicals Index Online |
subjects | Accidents Civil proceedings Compensation Consumer demand Consumer economics Health insurance Insurance coverage Insurance policies Insurance providers Juries Labour law Law Legal reform Liability Liability insurance Life insurance Pain and suffering Settlements & damages State court decisions Torts U.S.A United States Work accidents |
title | The Nonpecuniary Costs of Accidents: Pain-and-Suffering Damages in Tort Law |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-31T08%3A54%3A44IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-jstor_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=The%20Nonpecuniary%20Costs%20of%20Accidents:%20Pain-and-Suffering%20Damages%20in%20Tort%20Law&rft.jtitle=Harvard%20law%20review&rft.au=Croley,%20Steven%20P.&rft.date=1995-06-01&rft.volume=108&rft.issue=8&rft.spage=1785&rft.epage=1917&rft.pages=1785-1917&rft.issn=0017-811X&rft.eissn=2161-976X&rft.coden=HALRAF&rft_id=info:doi/10.2307/1341946&rft_dat=%3Cjstor_proqu%3E1341946%3C/jstor_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1290282479&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_jstor_id=1341946&rfr_iscdi=true |