A framework for social motives

In any complex social system, the choices of a single person often affect the outcomes of others. When one takes the others' outcomes into account in making choices, we say one is manifesting a social motive. We assume that an individual's social motives are manifested in his social prefer...

Ausführliche Beschreibung

Gespeichert in:
Bibliographische Detailangaben
Veröffentlicht in:Behavioral Science 1976-03, Vol.21 (2), p.86-100
Hauptverfasser: Maccrimmon, Kenneth R., Messick, David M.
Format: Artikel
Sprache:eng
Schlagworte:
Online-Zugang:Volltext
Tags: Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
container_end_page 100
container_issue 2
container_start_page 86
container_title Behavioral Science
container_volume 21
creator Maccrimmon, Kenneth R.
Messick, David M.
description In any complex social system, the choices of a single person often affect the outcomes of others. When one takes the others' outcomes into account in making choices, we say one is manifesting a social motive. We assume that an individual's social motives are manifested in his social preferences. Any theory of decision or choice requires information about preferences, and so in addition to attempting to clarify definitions of social motives, this study provides a framework for theories of social decision. To begin, we establish operational definitions for the motives of self‐interest, self‐sacrifice, altruism, aggression, cooperation, and competition. These definitions are based on the simple operators of summations and differences. Then we examine some supplementary motives involving proportionality operators. Next we eliminate the assumption that an individual has a fixed preference structure which is applied to all social choices. This leads to a focus on the specific distribution of consequences resulting in conditional motives; conditional motives reflect varying basic motives depending on whether the individual is ahead or behind. All these motives are represented graphically, and a correspondence matrix is given to illustrate the interrelationships among the motives. Finally, we investigate combinations of the motives since such composites are less restrictive and can better account for observed behavior. Linear combinations are interesting but still too restrictive. Conjunctive, disjunctive and lexicographic combinations offer useful possibilities for characterizing particular social motives. Complex combinations involving general nonlinear forms arise and some representative forms are explored.
doi_str_mv 10.1002/bs.3830210203
format Article
fullrecord <record><control><sourceid>proquest_cross</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_60834507</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><sourcerecordid>60834507</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3803-8f8e36b8f931b7ff47c0a116c76d03ed31496cf8352c48e6d8158ddc827b49dc3</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNp90FFLwzAQB_AgCs7po69SEHzrvPTSJH2c001l6IMTfQttmkC3dpnJ5ty3t7Kh6INPx8Hvf3ccIacUehQguSxCDyVCQiEB3CMdClkWU8Fwn3QAII1FxuCQHIUwbVvAlHfIWT-yPm_M2vlZZJ2PgtNVXkeNW1bvJhyTA5vXwZzsapc8D28mg9t4_Di6G_THsUYJGEsrDfJC2gxpIaxlQkNOKdeCl4CmRMoyrq3ENNFMGl5Kmsqy1DIRBctKjV1ysZ278O5tZcJSNVXQpq7zuXGroDhIZCmIFp7_gVO38vP2NkURaCJACmxVvFXauxC8sWrhqyb3G0VBff1KFUH9_Kr1YuvXVW02_2N19fQrudtUhaX5-E7mfqa4QJGql4eRwuvhQIjJvXrFT0fdeC4</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1301270873</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>A framework for social motives</title><source>Alma/SFX Local Collection</source><source>Sociological Abstracts</source><source>Periodicals Index Online</source><creator>Maccrimmon, Kenneth R. ; Messick, David M.</creator><creatorcontrib>Maccrimmon, Kenneth R. ; Messick, David M.</creatorcontrib><description>In any complex social system, the choices of a single person often affect the outcomes of others. When one takes the others' outcomes into account in making choices, we say one is manifesting a social motive. We assume that an individual's social motives are manifested in his social preferences. Any theory of decision or choice requires information about preferences, and so in addition to attempting to clarify definitions of social motives, this study provides a framework for theories of social decision. To begin, we establish operational definitions for the motives of self‐interest, self‐sacrifice, altruism, aggression, cooperation, and competition. These definitions are based on the simple operators of summations and differences. Then we examine some supplementary motives involving proportionality operators. Next we eliminate the assumption that an individual has a fixed preference structure which is applied to all social choices. This leads to a focus on the specific distribution of consequences resulting in conditional motives; conditional motives reflect varying basic motives depending on whether the individual is ahead or behind. All these motives are represented graphically, and a correspondence matrix is given to illustrate the interrelationships among the motives. Finally, we investigate combinations of the motives since such composites are less restrictive and can better account for observed behavior. Linear combinations are interesting but still too restrictive. Conjunctive, disjunctive and lexicographic combinations offer useful possibilities for characterizing particular social motives. Complex combinations involving general nonlinear forms arise and some representative forms are explored.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0005-7940</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1099-1743</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1932-300X</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1002/bs.3830210203</identifier><identifier>CODEN: BEHSAS</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>California: John Wiley &amp; Sons, Ltd</publisher><subject>cooperation and competition ; Decision/Decisional/Decisions ; Framework ; indifference curves ; interdependent preferences ; Motive/Motives/Motivation/ Motivational ; Social ; social choice ; social motives ; Theory/Theories/Theorem/ Theorizing</subject><ispartof>Behavioral Science, 1976-03, Vol.21 (2), p.86-100</ispartof><rights>Copyright © 1976 John Wiley &amp; Sons, Ltd.</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3803-8f8e36b8f931b7ff47c0a116c76d03ed31496cf8352c48e6d8158ddc827b49dc3</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3803-8f8e36b8f931b7ff47c0a116c76d03ed31496cf8352c48e6d8158ddc827b49dc3</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><link.rule.ids>314,776,780,27846,27901,27902,33752</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Maccrimmon, Kenneth R.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Messick, David M.</creatorcontrib><title>A framework for social motives</title><title>Behavioral Science</title><addtitle>Syst. Res</addtitle><description>In any complex social system, the choices of a single person often affect the outcomes of others. When one takes the others' outcomes into account in making choices, we say one is manifesting a social motive. We assume that an individual's social motives are manifested in his social preferences. Any theory of decision or choice requires information about preferences, and so in addition to attempting to clarify definitions of social motives, this study provides a framework for theories of social decision. To begin, we establish operational definitions for the motives of self‐interest, self‐sacrifice, altruism, aggression, cooperation, and competition. These definitions are based on the simple operators of summations and differences. Then we examine some supplementary motives involving proportionality operators. Next we eliminate the assumption that an individual has a fixed preference structure which is applied to all social choices. This leads to a focus on the specific distribution of consequences resulting in conditional motives; conditional motives reflect varying basic motives depending on whether the individual is ahead or behind. All these motives are represented graphically, and a correspondence matrix is given to illustrate the interrelationships among the motives. Finally, we investigate combinations of the motives since such composites are less restrictive and can better account for observed behavior. Linear combinations are interesting but still too restrictive. Conjunctive, disjunctive and lexicographic combinations offer useful possibilities for characterizing particular social motives. Complex combinations involving general nonlinear forms arise and some representative forms are explored.</description><subject>cooperation and competition</subject><subject>Decision/Decisional/Decisions</subject><subject>Framework</subject><subject>indifference curves</subject><subject>interdependent preferences</subject><subject>Motive/Motives/Motivation/ Motivational</subject><subject>Social</subject><subject>social choice</subject><subject>social motives</subject><subject>Theory/Theories/Theorem/ Theorizing</subject><issn>0005-7940</issn><issn>1099-1743</issn><issn>1932-300X</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>1976</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>0R3</sourceid><sourceid>ACFII</sourceid><sourceid>HYQOX</sourceid><sourceid>K30</sourceid><sourceid>~OC</sourceid><sourceid>~PJ</sourceid><sourceid>~PO</sourceid><sourceid>BHHNA</sourceid><recordid>eNp90FFLwzAQB_AgCs7po69SEHzrvPTSJH2c001l6IMTfQttmkC3dpnJ5ty3t7Kh6INPx8Hvf3ccIacUehQguSxCDyVCQiEB3CMdClkWU8Fwn3QAII1FxuCQHIUwbVvAlHfIWT-yPm_M2vlZZJ2PgtNVXkeNW1bvJhyTA5vXwZzsapc8D28mg9t4_Di6G_THsUYJGEsrDfJC2gxpIaxlQkNOKdeCl4CmRMoyrq3ENNFMGl5Kmsqy1DIRBctKjV1ysZ278O5tZcJSNVXQpq7zuXGroDhIZCmIFp7_gVO38vP2NkURaCJACmxVvFXauxC8sWrhqyb3G0VBff1KFUH9_Kr1YuvXVW02_2N19fQrudtUhaX5-E7mfqa4QJGql4eRwuvhQIjJvXrFT0fdeC4</recordid><startdate>197603</startdate><enddate>197603</enddate><creator>Maccrimmon, Kenneth R.</creator><creator>Messick, David M.</creator><general>John Wiley &amp; Sons, Ltd</general><general>University of Michigan, Mental Health Research Institute</general><scope>BSCLL</scope><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>0R3</scope><scope>ACFII</scope><scope>FYSDU</scope><scope>GHEHK</scope><scope>HYQOX</scope><scope>HZAIM</scope><scope>K30</scope><scope>PAAUG</scope><scope>PAWHS</scope><scope>PAWZZ</scope><scope>PAXOH</scope><scope>PBHAV</scope><scope>PBQSW</scope><scope>PBYQZ</scope><scope>PCIWU</scope><scope>PCMID</scope><scope>PCZJX</scope><scope>PDGRG</scope><scope>PDWWI</scope><scope>PETMR</scope><scope>PFVGT</scope><scope>PGXDX</scope><scope>PIHIL</scope><scope>PISVA</scope><scope>PJCTQ</scope><scope>PJTMS</scope><scope>PLCHJ</scope><scope>PMHAD</scope><scope>PNQDJ</scope><scope>POUND</scope><scope>PPLAD</scope><scope>PQAPC</scope><scope>PQCAN</scope><scope>PQCMW</scope><scope>PQEME</scope><scope>PQHKH</scope><scope>PQMID</scope><scope>PQNCT</scope><scope>PQNET</scope><scope>PQSCT</scope><scope>PQSET</scope><scope>PSVJG</scope><scope>PVMQY</scope><scope>PZGFC</scope><scope>~OB</scope><scope>~OC</scope><scope>~OG</scope><scope>~PJ</scope><scope>~PO</scope><scope>7U4</scope><scope>BHHNA</scope><scope>DWI</scope><scope>WZK</scope></search><sort><creationdate>197603</creationdate><title>A framework for social motives</title><author>Maccrimmon, Kenneth R. ; Messick, David M.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c3803-8f8e36b8f931b7ff47c0a116c76d03ed31496cf8352c48e6d8158ddc827b49dc3</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>1976</creationdate><topic>cooperation and competition</topic><topic>Decision/Decisional/Decisions</topic><topic>Framework</topic><topic>indifference curves</topic><topic>interdependent preferences</topic><topic>Motive/Motives/Motivation/ Motivational</topic><topic>Social</topic><topic>social choice</topic><topic>social motives</topic><topic>Theory/Theories/Theorem/ Theorizing</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Maccrimmon, Kenneth R.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Messick, David M.</creatorcontrib><collection>Istex</collection><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Periodicals Archive Online Collection 1.2</collection><collection>Periodicals Archive Online Foundation Collection 1 (2022)</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 07</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 08</collection><collection>ProQuest Historical Periodicals</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 26</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - West</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segments 1-50</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - MEA</collection><collection>PAO Collection 1</collection><collection>Periodicals Archive Online Collection 1</collection><collection>PAO Collection 1 (purchase pre Feb/2008)</collection><collection>Periodicals Archive Online Foundation Collection</collection><collection>Periodicals Archive Online Liberal Arts Collection 2</collection><collection>Sociological Abstracts (pre-2017)</collection><collection>Sociological Abstracts</collection><collection>Sociological Abstracts</collection><collection>Sociological Abstracts (Ovid)</collection><jtitle>Behavioral Science</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Maccrimmon, Kenneth R.</au><au>Messick, David M.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>A framework for social motives</atitle><jtitle>Behavioral Science</jtitle><addtitle>Syst. Res</addtitle><date>1976-03</date><risdate>1976</risdate><volume>21</volume><issue>2</issue><spage>86</spage><epage>100</epage><pages>86-100</pages><issn>0005-7940</issn><eissn>1099-1743</eissn><eissn>1932-300X</eissn><coden>BEHSAS</coden><abstract>In any complex social system, the choices of a single person often affect the outcomes of others. When one takes the others' outcomes into account in making choices, we say one is manifesting a social motive. We assume that an individual's social motives are manifested in his social preferences. Any theory of decision or choice requires information about preferences, and so in addition to attempting to clarify definitions of social motives, this study provides a framework for theories of social decision. To begin, we establish operational definitions for the motives of self‐interest, self‐sacrifice, altruism, aggression, cooperation, and competition. These definitions are based on the simple operators of summations and differences. Then we examine some supplementary motives involving proportionality operators. Next we eliminate the assumption that an individual has a fixed preference structure which is applied to all social choices. This leads to a focus on the specific distribution of consequences resulting in conditional motives; conditional motives reflect varying basic motives depending on whether the individual is ahead or behind. All these motives are represented graphically, and a correspondence matrix is given to illustrate the interrelationships among the motives. Finally, we investigate combinations of the motives since such composites are less restrictive and can better account for observed behavior. Linear combinations are interesting but still too restrictive. Conjunctive, disjunctive and lexicographic combinations offer useful possibilities for characterizing particular social motives. Complex combinations involving general nonlinear forms arise and some representative forms are explored.</abstract><cop>California</cop><pub>John Wiley &amp; Sons, Ltd</pub><doi>10.1002/bs.3830210203</doi><tpages>15</tpages></addata></record>
fulltext fulltext
identifier ISSN: 0005-7940
ispartof Behavioral Science, 1976-03, Vol.21 (2), p.86-100
issn 0005-7940
1099-1743
1932-300X
language eng
recordid cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_60834507
source Alma/SFX Local Collection; Sociological Abstracts; Periodicals Index Online
subjects cooperation and competition
Decision/Decisional/Decisions
Framework
indifference curves
interdependent preferences
Motive/Motives/Motivation/ Motivational
Social
social choice
social motives
Theory/Theories/Theorem/ Theorizing
title A framework for social motives
url https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-02-04T07%3A11%3A54IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-proquest_cross&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=A%20framework%20for%20social%20motives&rft.jtitle=Behavioral%20Science&rft.au=Maccrimmon,%20Kenneth%20R.&rft.date=1976-03&rft.volume=21&rft.issue=2&rft.spage=86&rft.epage=100&rft.pages=86-100&rft.issn=0005-7940&rft.eissn=1099-1743&rft.coden=BEHSAS&rft_id=info:doi/10.1002/bs.3830210203&rft_dat=%3Cproquest_cross%3E60834507%3C/proquest_cross%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1301270873&rft_id=info:pmid/&rfr_iscdi=true