Modelling labour market dynamics with on-the-job search
A flow model of the Dutch labour market is used to calculate the effects of policy options which aim to enhance employment, especially at the lower end of the labour market. The model distinguishes between good and bad jobs, allows for endogenous wage formation and job creation, and describes the fl...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Economic modelling 1999-12, Vol.16 (4), p.545-567 |
---|---|
Hauptverfasser: | , |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 567 |
---|---|
container_issue | 4 |
container_start_page | 545 |
container_title | Economic modelling |
container_volume | 16 |
creator | den Butter, Frank A.G Gorter, Cees |
description | A flow model of the Dutch labour market is used to calculate the effects of policy options which aim to enhance employment, especially at the lower end of the labour market. The model distinguishes between good and bad jobs, allows for endogenous wage formation and job creation, and describes the flows between these jobs so that job-to-job mobility and the vacancy chain is made endogenous. In the matching process employed job seekers with bad jobs compete with short-term and long-term unemployed for the filling of vacancies for good jobs. In each period part of the good and bad jobs are destroyed which results in inflow into unemployment. The model explicitly describes the flow of unemployed through the various duration classes of unemployment and it allows for negative duration dependence so that the escape probability from unemployment for long-term unemployed is smaller than for short-term unemployed. The model is used to simulate the effects of external shocks, such as structural productivity shocks. An impulse response analysis using the model is also conducted considering labour market policies which aims especially to enhance employment at the lower end of the labour market. In particular, the effects are analysed of measures subsidising the opening of bad jobs (jobs at the lower end of the labour market) and a rise in the productivity of a bad job as compared to a good job which can be achieved by changes in the tax system. |
doi_str_mv | 10.1016/S0264-9993(99)00013-9 |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>proquest_cross</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_38806792</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><els_id>S0264999399000139</els_id><sourcerecordid>38806792</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c569t-a51e4d152790db717598b709ba417fc44ca45e97811179819f3cfa2a2d48a52e3</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqFkE2LFDEQhoMoOK7-BKFREPfQmsp3TrIsuiorHtRzSKernYzT3WPSszL_3pod2YMgBiqVw_MWlYexp8BfAQfz-gsXRrXee_nS-3POOcjW32MrcFa2BoS4z1Z3yEP2qNYNQQKUXzH7ae5xu83T92Ybu3lfmjGWH7g0_WGKY061-ZWXdTNP7bLGdjN3TcVY0voxezDEbcUnf_oZ-_bu7dfL9-3156sPlxfXbdLGL23UgKoHLaznfWfBau86y30XFdghKZWi0uitAwDrHfhBpiGKKHrlohYoz9iL09xdmX_usS5hzDXRxnHCeV-DdI4b6wWBz_4CN_SbiXYLAsAYy4Um6Pm_IDBOOi6UckTpE5XKXGvBIexKJi2HADwcjYdb4-Gok65wazx4yn085QruMN2FkE4aSXO4CTJSWsbD8UFxaplKUe2otNJBGxvWy0jD3pyGIdm9yVhCTRmnhH0umJbQz_k_6_wGImKeYg</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1683802448</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Modelling labour market dynamics with on-the-job search</title><source>RePEc</source><source>Periodicals Index Online</source><source>ScienceDirect Journals (5 years ago - present)</source><creator>den Butter, Frank A.G ; Gorter, Cees</creator><creatorcontrib>den Butter, Frank A.G ; Gorter, Cees</creatorcontrib><description>A flow model of the Dutch labour market is used to calculate the effects of policy options which aim to enhance employment, especially at the lower end of the labour market. The model distinguishes between good and bad jobs, allows for endogenous wage formation and job creation, and describes the flows between these jobs so that job-to-job mobility and the vacancy chain is made endogenous. In the matching process employed job seekers with bad jobs compete with short-term and long-term unemployed for the filling of vacancies for good jobs. In each period part of the good and bad jobs are destroyed which results in inflow into unemployment. The model explicitly describes the flow of unemployed through the various duration classes of unemployment and it allows for negative duration dependence so that the escape probability from unemployment for long-term unemployed is smaller than for short-term unemployed. The model is used to simulate the effects of external shocks, such as structural productivity shocks. An impulse response analysis using the model is also conducted considering labour market policies which aims especially to enhance employment at the lower end of the labour market. In particular, the effects are analysed of measures subsidising the opening of bad jobs (jobs at the lower end of the labour market) and a rise in the productivity of a bad job as compared to a good job which can be achieved by changes in the tax system.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0264-9993</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1873-6122</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1016/S0264-9993(99)00013-9</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>London: Elsevier B.V</publisher><subject>Economic dynamics ; Economic models ; Employment ; Employment creation ; Job creation ; Job search ; Labor market ; Labour market ; Labour market flows ; Labour productivity ; Modelling ; On-the-job search ; Studies ; Unemployed ; Unemployment ; Wages & salaries</subject><ispartof>Economic modelling, 1999-12, Vol.16 (4), p.545-567</ispartof><rights>1999 Elsevier Science B.V.</rights><rights>Copyright Elsevier Science Ltd. Dec 1999</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><oa>free_for_read</oa><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c569t-a51e4d152790db717598b709ba417fc44ca45e97811179819f3cfa2a2d48a52e3</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c569t-a51e4d152790db717598b709ba417fc44ca45e97811179819f3cfa2a2d48a52e3</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0264-9993(99)00013-9$$EHTML$$P50$$Gelsevier$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,780,784,3548,4006,27868,27923,27924,45994</link.rule.ids><backlink>$$Uhttp://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeeecmode/v_3a16_3ay_3a1999_3ai_3a4_3ap_3a545-567.htm$$DView record in RePEc$$Hfree_for_read</backlink></links><search><creatorcontrib>den Butter, Frank A.G</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Gorter, Cees</creatorcontrib><title>Modelling labour market dynamics with on-the-job search</title><title>Economic modelling</title><description>A flow model of the Dutch labour market is used to calculate the effects of policy options which aim to enhance employment, especially at the lower end of the labour market. The model distinguishes between good and bad jobs, allows for endogenous wage formation and job creation, and describes the flows between these jobs so that job-to-job mobility and the vacancy chain is made endogenous. In the matching process employed job seekers with bad jobs compete with short-term and long-term unemployed for the filling of vacancies for good jobs. In each period part of the good and bad jobs are destroyed which results in inflow into unemployment. The model explicitly describes the flow of unemployed through the various duration classes of unemployment and it allows for negative duration dependence so that the escape probability from unemployment for long-term unemployed is smaller than for short-term unemployed. The model is used to simulate the effects of external shocks, such as structural productivity shocks. An impulse response analysis using the model is also conducted considering labour market policies which aims especially to enhance employment at the lower end of the labour market. In particular, the effects are analysed of measures subsidising the opening of bad jobs (jobs at the lower end of the labour market) and a rise in the productivity of a bad job as compared to a good job which can be achieved by changes in the tax system.</description><subject>Economic dynamics</subject><subject>Economic models</subject><subject>Employment</subject><subject>Employment creation</subject><subject>Job creation</subject><subject>Job search</subject><subject>Labor market</subject><subject>Labour market</subject><subject>Labour market flows</subject><subject>Labour productivity</subject><subject>Modelling</subject><subject>On-the-job search</subject><subject>Studies</subject><subject>Unemployed</subject><subject>Unemployment</subject><subject>Wages & salaries</subject><issn>0264-9993</issn><issn>1873-6122</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>1999</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>X2L</sourceid><sourceid>K30</sourceid><recordid>eNqFkE2LFDEQhoMoOK7-BKFREPfQmsp3TrIsuiorHtRzSKernYzT3WPSszL_3pod2YMgBiqVw_MWlYexp8BfAQfz-gsXRrXee_nS-3POOcjW32MrcFa2BoS4z1Z3yEP2qNYNQQKUXzH7ae5xu83T92Ybu3lfmjGWH7g0_WGKY061-ZWXdTNP7bLGdjN3TcVY0voxezDEbcUnf_oZ-_bu7dfL9-3156sPlxfXbdLGL23UgKoHLaznfWfBau86y30XFdghKZWi0uitAwDrHfhBpiGKKHrlohYoz9iL09xdmX_usS5hzDXRxnHCeV-DdI4b6wWBz_4CN_SbiXYLAsAYy4Um6Pm_IDBOOi6UckTpE5XKXGvBIexKJi2HADwcjYdb4-Gok65wazx4yn085QruMN2FkE4aSXO4CTJSWsbD8UFxaplKUe2otNJBGxvWy0jD3pyGIdm9yVhCTRmnhH0umJbQz_k_6_wGImKeYg</recordid><startdate>19991201</startdate><enddate>19991201</enddate><creator>den Butter, Frank A.G</creator><creator>Gorter, Cees</creator><general>Elsevier B.V</general><general>Elsevier</general><general>Butterworths</general><general>Elsevier Science Ltd</general><scope>DKI</scope><scope>X2L</scope><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>HFIND</scope><scope>HZAIM</scope><scope>K30</scope><scope>PAAUG</scope><scope>PAWHS</scope><scope>PAWZZ</scope><scope>PAXOH</scope><scope>PBHAV</scope><scope>PBQSW</scope><scope>PBYQZ</scope><scope>PCIWU</scope><scope>PCMID</scope><scope>PCZJX</scope><scope>PDGRG</scope><scope>PDWWI</scope><scope>PETMR</scope><scope>PFVGT</scope><scope>PGXDX</scope><scope>PIHIL</scope><scope>PISVA</scope><scope>PJCTQ</scope><scope>PJTMS</scope><scope>PLCHJ</scope><scope>PMHAD</scope><scope>PNQDJ</scope><scope>POUND</scope><scope>PPLAD</scope><scope>PQAPC</scope><scope>PQCAN</scope><scope>PQCMW</scope><scope>PQEME</scope><scope>PQHKH</scope><scope>PQMID</scope><scope>PQNCT</scope><scope>PQNET</scope><scope>PQSCT</scope><scope>PQSET</scope><scope>PSVJG</scope><scope>PVMQY</scope><scope>PZGFC</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope></search><sort><creationdate>19991201</creationdate><title>Modelling labour market dynamics with on-the-job search</title><author>den Butter, Frank A.G ; Gorter, Cees</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c569t-a51e4d152790db717598b709ba417fc44ca45e97811179819f3cfa2a2d48a52e3</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>1999</creationdate><topic>Economic dynamics</topic><topic>Economic models</topic><topic>Employment</topic><topic>Employment creation</topic><topic>Job creation</topic><topic>Job search</topic><topic>Labor market</topic><topic>Labour market</topic><topic>Labour market flows</topic><topic>Labour productivity</topic><topic>Modelling</topic><topic>On-the-job search</topic><topic>Studies</topic><topic>Unemployed</topic><topic>Unemployment</topic><topic>Wages & salaries</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>den Butter, Frank A.G</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Gorter, Cees</creatorcontrib><collection>RePEc IDEAS</collection><collection>RePEc</collection><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 16</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 26</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - West</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segments 1-50</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - MEA</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><jtitle>Economic modelling</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>den Butter, Frank A.G</au><au>Gorter, Cees</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Modelling labour market dynamics with on-the-job search</atitle><jtitle>Economic modelling</jtitle><date>1999-12-01</date><risdate>1999</risdate><volume>16</volume><issue>4</issue><spage>545</spage><epage>567</epage><pages>545-567</pages><issn>0264-9993</issn><eissn>1873-6122</eissn><abstract>A flow model of the Dutch labour market is used to calculate the effects of policy options which aim to enhance employment, especially at the lower end of the labour market. The model distinguishes between good and bad jobs, allows for endogenous wage formation and job creation, and describes the flows between these jobs so that job-to-job mobility and the vacancy chain is made endogenous. In the matching process employed job seekers with bad jobs compete with short-term and long-term unemployed for the filling of vacancies for good jobs. In each period part of the good and bad jobs are destroyed which results in inflow into unemployment. The model explicitly describes the flow of unemployed through the various duration classes of unemployment and it allows for negative duration dependence so that the escape probability from unemployment for long-term unemployed is smaller than for short-term unemployed. The model is used to simulate the effects of external shocks, such as structural productivity shocks. An impulse response analysis using the model is also conducted considering labour market policies which aims especially to enhance employment at the lower end of the labour market. In particular, the effects are analysed of measures subsidising the opening of bad jobs (jobs at the lower end of the labour market) and a rise in the productivity of a bad job as compared to a good job which can be achieved by changes in the tax system.</abstract><cop>London</cop><pub>Elsevier B.V</pub><doi>10.1016/S0264-9993(99)00013-9</doi><tpages>23</tpages><oa>free_for_read</oa></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0264-9993 |
ispartof | Economic modelling, 1999-12, Vol.16 (4), p.545-567 |
issn | 0264-9993 1873-6122 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_38806792 |
source | RePEc; Periodicals Index Online; ScienceDirect Journals (5 years ago - present) |
subjects | Economic dynamics Economic models Employment Employment creation Job creation Job search Labor market Labour market Labour market flows Labour productivity Modelling On-the-job search Studies Unemployed Unemployment Wages & salaries |
title | Modelling labour market dynamics with on-the-job search |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-12T08%3A43%3A52IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-proquest_cross&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Modelling%20labour%20market%20dynamics%20with%20on-the-job%20search&rft.jtitle=Economic%20modelling&rft.au=den%20Butter,%20Frank%20A.G&rft.date=1999-12-01&rft.volume=16&rft.issue=4&rft.spage=545&rft.epage=567&rft.pages=545-567&rft.issn=0264-9993&rft.eissn=1873-6122&rft_id=info:doi/10.1016/S0264-9993(99)00013-9&rft_dat=%3Cproquest_cross%3E38806792%3C/proquest_cross%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1683802448&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_els_id=S0264999399000139&rfr_iscdi=true |