Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets
We investigate the optimal behavior of a public firm in a mixed market involving private firms and one public firm. Existing works show that welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is suboptimal when the number of firms is given exogenously. We allow free entry of private firms and find that,...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Journal of economics (Vienna, Austria) Austria), 2005-02, Vol.84 (1), p.27-48 |
---|---|
Hauptverfasser: | , |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 48 |
---|---|
container_issue | 1 |
container_start_page | 27 |
container_title | Journal of economics (Vienna, Austria) |
container_volume | 84 |
creator | Matsumura, Toshihiro Kanda, Osamu |
description | We investigate the optimal behavior of a public firm in a mixed market involving private firms and one public firm. Existing works show that welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is suboptimal when the number of firms is given exogenously. We allow free entry of private firms and find that, in contrast to the case with the fixed number of firms, welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is always optimal in mixed markets. Furthermore, we find that mixed markets are better than pure markets involving no public firm if and only if the public firm earns nonnegative profits. |
doi_str_mv | 10.1007/s00712-004-0098-z |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>jstor_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_38053164</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><jstor_id>41795214</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>41795214</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c387t-846f4fe9c9fea2b09a97385cac2b78fff68757eaf94d368e6a1961acc93a37bd3</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNpdkE1LAzEQhoMoWKs_wIOwCHqLZjbZfByltCq09KLnkM0msnXb1GQLtr_elBUPHuady_MOw4PQNZAHIEQ8phxQYkJYHiXx4QSNgIPAAig7RSOiKGDJK3mOLlJakQxyLkbobtF-u6ZYdu1H2IZuX5i-mEXniummj_tiYeKn69MlOvOmS-7qd4_R-2z6NnnB8-Xz6-Rpji2VoseScc-8U1Z5Z8qaKKMElZU1tqyF9N5zKSrhjFesoVw6bkBxMNYqaqioGzpG98PdbQxfO5d6vW6TdV1nNi7skqaSVBQ4y-DtP3AVdnGTf9Ml4VwxRY8QDJCNIaXovN7Gdm3iXgPRR2t6sKazDH20pg-5czN0VqkP8a_AQKiqBEZ_ACH4aC8</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>206694934</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets</title><source>Jstor Complete Legacy</source><source>Springer Nature - Complete Springer Journals</source><source>Business Source Complete</source><creator>Matsumura, Toshihiro ; Kanda, Osamu</creator><creatorcontrib>Matsumura, Toshihiro ; Kanda, Osamu</creatorcontrib><description>We investigate the optimal behavior of a public firm in a mixed market involving private firms and one public firm. Existing works show that welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is suboptimal when the number of firms is given exogenously. We allow free entry of private firms and find that, in contrast to the case with the fixed number of firms, welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is always optimal in mixed markets. Furthermore, we find that mixed markets are better than pure markets involving no public firm if and only if the public firm earns nonnegative profits.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0931-8658</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1617-7134</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1007/s00712-004-0098-z</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Wien: Springer-Verlag</publisher><subject>Average cost ; Banking ; Business structures ; Cost functions ; Cost of entry ; Economic theory ; Economics ; Enterprises ; Financial performance ; Free entry ; Marginal costs ; Market ; Market entry ; Monopolistic competition ; Oligopolies ; Oligopoly ; Private sector ; Privatization ; Profit ; Public enterprise ; Public sector ; Publicly traded corporations ; Restriction ; Restrictions ; Studies ; Welfare losses</subject><ispartof>Journal of economics (Vienna, Austria), 2005-02, Vol.84 (1), p.27-48</ispartof><rights>Springer-Verlag Wien 2005</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c387t-846f4fe9c9fea2b09a97385cac2b78fff68757eaf94d368e6a1961acc93a37bd3</citedby></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/41795214$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/41795214$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,776,780,799,27903,27904,57995,58228</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Matsumura, Toshihiro</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Kanda, Osamu</creatorcontrib><title>Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets</title><title>Journal of economics (Vienna, Austria)</title><description>We investigate the optimal behavior of a public firm in a mixed market involving private firms and one public firm. Existing works show that welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is suboptimal when the number of firms is given exogenously. We allow free entry of private firms and find that, in contrast to the case with the fixed number of firms, welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is always optimal in mixed markets. Furthermore, we find that mixed markets are better than pure markets involving no public firm if and only if the public firm earns nonnegative profits.</description><subject>Average cost</subject><subject>Banking</subject><subject>Business structures</subject><subject>Cost functions</subject><subject>Cost of entry</subject><subject>Economic theory</subject><subject>Economics</subject><subject>Enterprises</subject><subject>Financial performance</subject><subject>Free entry</subject><subject>Marginal costs</subject><subject>Market</subject><subject>Market entry</subject><subject>Monopolistic competition</subject><subject>Oligopolies</subject><subject>Oligopoly</subject><subject>Private sector</subject><subject>Privatization</subject><subject>Profit</subject><subject>Public enterprise</subject><subject>Public sector</subject><subject>Publicly traded corporations</subject><subject>Restriction</subject><subject>Restrictions</subject><subject>Studies</subject><subject>Welfare losses</subject><issn>0931-8658</issn><issn>1617-7134</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2005</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>BENPR</sourceid><recordid>eNpdkE1LAzEQhoMoWKs_wIOwCHqLZjbZfByltCq09KLnkM0msnXb1GQLtr_elBUPHuady_MOw4PQNZAHIEQ8phxQYkJYHiXx4QSNgIPAAig7RSOiKGDJK3mOLlJakQxyLkbobtF-u6ZYdu1H2IZuX5i-mEXniummj_tiYeKn69MlOvOmS-7qd4_R-2z6NnnB8-Xz6-Rpji2VoseScc-8U1Z5Z8qaKKMElZU1tqyF9N5zKSrhjFesoVw6bkBxMNYqaqioGzpG98PdbQxfO5d6vW6TdV1nNi7skqaSVBQ4y-DtP3AVdnGTf9Ml4VwxRY8QDJCNIaXovN7Gdm3iXgPRR2t6sKazDH20pg-5czN0VqkP8a_AQKiqBEZ_ACH4aC8</recordid><startdate>20050201</startdate><enddate>20050201</enddate><creator>Matsumura, Toshihiro</creator><creator>Kanda, Osamu</creator><general>Springer-Verlag</general><general>Springer Nature B.V</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>0U~</scope><scope>1-H</scope><scope>3V.</scope><scope>7WY</scope><scope>7WZ</scope><scope>7XB</scope><scope>87Z</scope><scope>8AO</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>8FK</scope><scope>8FL</scope><scope>ABUWG</scope><scope>AFKRA</scope><scope>BENPR</scope><scope>BEZIV</scope><scope>CCPQU</scope><scope>DWQXO</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>FRNLG</scope><scope>F~G</scope><scope>JBE</scope><scope>K60</scope><scope>K6~</scope><scope>K8~</scope><scope>L.-</scope><scope>L.0</scope><scope>M0C</scope><scope>PQBIZ</scope><scope>PQBZA</scope><scope>PQEST</scope><scope>PQQKQ</scope><scope>PQUKI</scope><scope>Q9U</scope></search><sort><creationdate>20050201</creationdate><title>Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets</title><author>Matsumura, Toshihiro ; Kanda, Osamu</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c387t-846f4fe9c9fea2b09a97385cac2b78fff68757eaf94d368e6a1961acc93a37bd3</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2005</creationdate><topic>Average cost</topic><topic>Banking</topic><topic>Business structures</topic><topic>Cost functions</topic><topic>Cost of entry</topic><topic>Economic theory</topic><topic>Economics</topic><topic>Enterprises</topic><topic>Financial performance</topic><topic>Free entry</topic><topic>Marginal costs</topic><topic>Market</topic><topic>Market entry</topic><topic>Monopolistic competition</topic><topic>Oligopolies</topic><topic>Oligopoly</topic><topic>Private sector</topic><topic>Privatization</topic><topic>Profit</topic><topic>Public enterprise</topic><topic>Public sector</topic><topic>Publicly traded corporations</topic><topic>Restriction</topic><topic>Restrictions</topic><topic>Studies</topic><topic>Welfare losses</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Matsumura, Toshihiro</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Kanda, Osamu</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Global News & ABI/Inform Professional</collection><collection>Trade PRO</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Corporate)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Collection</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (PDF only)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Pharma Collection</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni) (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Collection (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central UK/Ireland</collection><collection>ProQuest Central</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest One Community College</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Korea</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection (Alumni)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (Corporate)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection</collection><collection>DELNET Management Collection</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Professional Advanced</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Professional Standard</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business (Alumni)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic Eastern Edition (DO NOT USE)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic UKI Edition</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Basic</collection><jtitle>Journal of economics (Vienna, Austria)</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Matsumura, Toshihiro</au><au>Kanda, Osamu</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets</atitle><jtitle>Journal of economics (Vienna, Austria)</jtitle><date>2005-02-01</date><risdate>2005</risdate><volume>84</volume><issue>1</issue><spage>27</spage><epage>48</epage><pages>27-48</pages><issn>0931-8658</issn><eissn>1617-7134</eissn><abstract>We investigate the optimal behavior of a public firm in a mixed market involving private firms and one public firm. Existing works show that welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is suboptimal when the number of firms is given exogenously. We allow free entry of private firms and find that, in contrast to the case with the fixed number of firms, welfare-maximizing behavior by the public firm is always optimal in mixed markets. Furthermore, we find that mixed markets are better than pure markets involving no public firm if and only if the public firm earns nonnegative profits.</abstract><cop>Wien</cop><pub>Springer-Verlag</pub><doi>10.1007/s00712-004-0098-z</doi><tpages>22</tpages></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0931-8658 |
ispartof | Journal of economics (Vienna, Austria), 2005-02, Vol.84 (1), p.27-48 |
issn | 0931-8658 1617-7134 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_38053164 |
source | Jstor Complete Legacy; Springer Nature - Complete Springer Journals; Business Source Complete |
subjects | Average cost Banking Business structures Cost functions Cost of entry Economic theory Economics Enterprises Financial performance Free entry Marginal costs Market Market entry Monopolistic competition Oligopolies Oligopoly Private sector Privatization Profit Public enterprise Public sector Publicly traded corporations Restriction Restrictions Studies Welfare losses |
title | Mixed Oligopoly at Free Entry Markets |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-27T07%3A16%3A12IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-jstor_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Mixed%20Oligopoly%20at%20Free%20Entry%20Markets&rft.jtitle=Journal%20of%20economics%20(Vienna,%20Austria)&rft.au=Matsumura,%20Toshihiro&rft.date=2005-02-01&rft.volume=84&rft.issue=1&rft.spage=27&rft.epage=48&rft.pages=27-48&rft.issn=0931-8658&rft.eissn=1617-7134&rft_id=info:doi/10.1007/s00712-004-0098-z&rft_dat=%3Cjstor_proqu%3E41795214%3C/jstor_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=206694934&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_jstor_id=41795214&rfr_iscdi=true |