Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation

Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings...

Ausführliche Beschreibung

Gespeichert in:
Bibliographische Detailangaben
Veröffentlicht in:Southern economic journal 2005-10, Vol.72 (2), p.463-481
Hauptverfasser: Liu, Liqun, Saving, Thomas R.
Format: Artikel
Sprache:eng
Schlagworte:
Online-Zugang:Volltext
Tags: Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
container_end_page 481
container_issue 2
container_start_page 463
container_title Southern economic journal
container_volume 72
creator Liu, Liqun
Saving, Thomas R.
description Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings of others that consumer welfare and overall welfare are always higher under ad valorem taxation. However, ad valorem taxation generates larger profits (hence Pareto dominates) only when market demand is elastic, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit taxation in markets with inelastic demand. The effects on ad valorem Pareto dominance of within- and between-market substitutability, number of firms in the taxed market, and the level of taxation are also investigated. In the long run, an equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation reduces consumer price, which is welfare improving, but also reduces variety when market demand is elastic, which is welfare decreasing. Nonetheless, ad valorem welfare dominance still holds in the long run.
doi_str_mv 10.1002/j.2325-8012.2005.tb00713.x
format Article
fullrecord <record><control><sourceid>gale_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_37707459</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><galeid>A138225507</galeid><jstor_id>20062122</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>A138225507</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3933-21e6f4460375c245eb6ed4bfbf4b8b633a888669bb58e6d285a1c4370cccf7ae3</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqVkV1r1TAch4MoeJz7DmWgd615bXK8Oxw3X5hssOltSNN_ZmvbzCTFs29vaseQsRsppCF5nh9JfgidEFwRjOm7vqKMilJhQiuKsahSg7EkrDo8Q5uHredogzFTJc_DS_Qqxh5nmRCxQfuvJvyEVFzNTUxdmlPnp8JMbZF-QHFpAiRffPBjN5nJQuFdsWuL72bwAcbi2hzMwr9GL5wZIhzf_4_Qt7PT6_2n8vzi4-f97ry0bMtYSQnUjvMaMyks5QKaGlreuMbxRjU1Y0YpVdfbphEK6pYqYYjlTGJrrZMG2BF6u-beBv9rhpj02EULw2Am8HPUTEosudhm8OQR2Ps5TPlsmhJKOK0pyVC5QjdmAN1Nzqdg7A1MEPL9JnBdXt4RpigVAsvMV0_w-Wth7OyTwvtVsMHHGMDp29CNJtxpgvXSnu71UpFeKtJLe_q-PX3I8m6Vf-fUu_8w9dXF6Ze_85zxZs3oY_Lh3wzKsFy8_A6Usj8ihKui</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>212142621</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation</title><source>Business Source Complete</source><source>Access via Wiley Online Library</source><source>JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing</source><creator>Liu, Liqun ; Saving, Thomas R.</creator><creatorcontrib>Liu, Liqun ; Saving, Thomas R.</creatorcontrib><description>Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings of others that consumer welfare and overall welfare are always higher under ad valorem taxation. However, ad valorem taxation generates larger profits (hence Pareto dominates) only when market demand is elastic, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit taxation in markets with inelastic demand. The effects on ad valorem Pareto dominance of within- and between-market substitutability, number of firms in the taxed market, and the level of taxation are also investigated. In the long run, an equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation reduces consumer price, which is welfare improving, but also reduces variety when market demand is elastic, which is welfare decreasing. Nonetheless, ad valorem welfare dominance still holds in the long run.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0038-4038</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 2325-8012</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1002/j.2325-8012.2005.tb00713.x</identifier><identifier>CODEN: SECJAR</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Stillwater: Southern Economic Association</publisher><subject>Ad valorem taxes ; Consumer advertising ; Consumers ; Consumption ; Economic aspects ; Economic models ; Economics ; Efficiency ; Elasticity of demand ; Equilibrium ; Excise taxes ; Expenditures ; Income taxes ; Market ; Market demand ; Market prices ; Oligopolies ; Pareto efficiency ; Pareto optimum ; Price elasticity ; Prices ; Product differentiation ; Profitability ; Profits ; Studies ; Tax policy ; Tax revenues ; Taxation ; Utility functions ; Welfare</subject><ispartof>Southern economic journal, 2005-10, Vol.72 (2), p.463-481</ispartof><rights>Copyright 2005 Southern Economic Association</rights><rights>2005 Southern Economic Association</rights><rights>COPYRIGHT 2005 Southern Economic Association</rights><rights>(c)2005 Southern Economic Association</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3933-21e6f4460375c245eb6ed4bfbf4b8b633a888669bb58e6d285a1c4370cccf7ae3</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3933-21e6f4460375c245eb6ed4bfbf4b8b633a888669bb58e6d285a1c4370cccf7ae3</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/20062122$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/20062122$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>315,782,786,805,1419,27931,27932,45581,45582,58024,58257</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Liu, Liqun</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Saving, Thomas R.</creatorcontrib><title>Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation</title><title>Southern economic journal</title><description>Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings of others that consumer welfare and overall welfare are always higher under ad valorem taxation. However, ad valorem taxation generates larger profits (hence Pareto dominates) only when market demand is elastic, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit taxation in markets with inelastic demand. The effects on ad valorem Pareto dominance of within- and between-market substitutability, number of firms in the taxed market, and the level of taxation are also investigated. In the long run, an equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation reduces consumer price, which is welfare improving, but also reduces variety when market demand is elastic, which is welfare decreasing. Nonetheless, ad valorem welfare dominance still holds in the long run.</description><subject>Ad valorem taxes</subject><subject>Consumer advertising</subject><subject>Consumers</subject><subject>Consumption</subject><subject>Economic aspects</subject><subject>Economic models</subject><subject>Economics</subject><subject>Efficiency</subject><subject>Elasticity of demand</subject><subject>Equilibrium</subject><subject>Excise taxes</subject><subject>Expenditures</subject><subject>Income taxes</subject><subject>Market</subject><subject>Market demand</subject><subject>Market prices</subject><subject>Oligopolies</subject><subject>Pareto efficiency</subject><subject>Pareto optimum</subject><subject>Price elasticity</subject><subject>Prices</subject><subject>Product differentiation</subject><subject>Profitability</subject><subject>Profits</subject><subject>Studies</subject><subject>Tax policy</subject><subject>Tax revenues</subject><subject>Taxation</subject><subject>Utility functions</subject><subject>Welfare</subject><issn>0038-4038</issn><issn>2325-8012</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2005</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>8G5</sourceid><sourceid>ABUWG</sourceid><sourceid>AFKRA</sourceid><sourceid>AZQEC</sourceid><sourceid>BEC</sourceid><sourceid>BENPR</sourceid><sourceid>CCPQU</sourceid><sourceid>DWQXO</sourceid><sourceid>GNUQQ</sourceid><sourceid>GUQSH</sourceid><sourceid>M2O</sourceid><recordid>eNqVkV1r1TAch4MoeJz7DmWgd615bXK8Oxw3X5hssOltSNN_ZmvbzCTFs29vaseQsRsppCF5nh9JfgidEFwRjOm7vqKMilJhQiuKsahSg7EkrDo8Q5uHredogzFTJc_DS_Qqxh5nmRCxQfuvJvyEVFzNTUxdmlPnp8JMbZF-QHFpAiRffPBjN5nJQuFdsWuL72bwAcbi2hzMwr9GL5wZIhzf_4_Qt7PT6_2n8vzi4-f97ry0bMtYSQnUjvMaMyks5QKaGlreuMbxRjU1Y0YpVdfbphEK6pYqYYjlTGJrrZMG2BF6u-beBv9rhpj02EULw2Am8HPUTEosudhm8OQR2Ps5TPlsmhJKOK0pyVC5QjdmAN1Nzqdg7A1MEPL9JnBdXt4RpigVAsvMV0_w-Wth7OyTwvtVsMHHGMDp29CNJtxpgvXSnu71UpFeKtJLe_q-PX3I8m6Vf-fUu_8w9dXF6Ze_85zxZs3oY_Lh3wzKsFy8_A6Usj8ihKui</recordid><startdate>200510</startdate><enddate>200510</enddate><creator>Liu, Liqun</creator><creator>Saving, Thomas R.</creator><general>Southern Economic Association</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>0-V</scope><scope>0U~</scope><scope>1-H</scope><scope>3V.</scope><scope>4S-</scope><scope>4T-</scope><scope>7WY</scope><scope>7WZ</scope><scope>7XB</scope><scope>87Z</scope><scope>88J</scope><scope>8AO</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>8FK</scope><scope>8FL</scope><scope>8G5</scope><scope>ABUWG</scope><scope>AFKRA</scope><scope>ALSLI</scope><scope>AZQEC</scope><scope>BEC</scope><scope>BENPR</scope><scope>BEZIV</scope><scope>CCPQU</scope><scope>DWQXO</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>FRNLG</scope><scope>F~G</scope><scope>GNUQQ</scope><scope>GUQSH</scope><scope>JBE</scope><scope>K60</scope><scope>K6~</scope><scope>L.-</scope><scope>L.0</scope><scope>M0C</scope><scope>M2O</scope><scope>M2R</scope><scope>MBDVC</scope><scope>PQBIZ</scope><scope>PQBZA</scope><scope>PQEST</scope><scope>PQQKQ</scope><scope>PQUKI</scope><scope>PRINS</scope><scope>Q9U</scope><scope>S0X</scope></search><sort><creationdate>200510</creationdate><title>Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation</title><author>Liu, Liqun ; Saving, Thomas R.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c3933-21e6f4460375c245eb6ed4bfbf4b8b633a888669bb58e6d285a1c4370cccf7ae3</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2005</creationdate><topic>Ad valorem taxes</topic><topic>Consumer advertising</topic><topic>Consumers</topic><topic>Consumption</topic><topic>Economic aspects</topic><topic>Economic models</topic><topic>Economics</topic><topic>Efficiency</topic><topic>Elasticity of demand</topic><topic>Equilibrium</topic><topic>Excise taxes</topic><topic>Expenditures</topic><topic>Income taxes</topic><topic>Market</topic><topic>Market demand</topic><topic>Market prices</topic><topic>Oligopolies</topic><topic>Pareto efficiency</topic><topic>Pareto optimum</topic><topic>Price elasticity</topic><topic>Prices</topic><topic>Product differentiation</topic><topic>Profitability</topic><topic>Profits</topic><topic>Studies</topic><topic>Tax policy</topic><topic>Tax revenues</topic><topic>Taxation</topic><topic>Utility functions</topic><topic>Welfare</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Liu, Liqun</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Saving, Thomas R.</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>ProQuest Social Sciences Premium Collection</collection><collection>Global News &amp; ABI/Inform Professional</collection><collection>Trade PRO</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Corporate)</collection><collection>BPIR.com Limited</collection><collection>Docstoc</collection><collection>Access via ABI/INFORM (ProQuest)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (PDF only)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>Social Science Database (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Pharma Collection</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni) (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Collection (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>Research Library (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central UK/Ireland</collection><collection>Social Science Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Essentials</collection><collection>eLibrary</collection><collection>ProQuest Central</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest One Community College</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Korea</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection (Alumni)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (Corporate)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Student</collection><collection>Research Library Prep</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Professional Advanced</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Professional Standard</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global</collection><collection>Research Library</collection><collection>Social Science Database</collection><collection>Research Library (Corporate)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business (Alumni)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic Eastern Edition (DO NOT USE)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic UKI Edition</collection><collection>ProQuest Central China</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Basic</collection><collection>SIRS Editorial</collection><jtitle>Southern economic journal</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Liu, Liqun</au><au>Saving, Thomas R.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation</atitle><jtitle>Southern economic journal</jtitle><date>2005-10</date><risdate>2005</risdate><volume>72</volume><issue>2</issue><spage>463</spage><epage>481</epage><pages>463-481</pages><issn>0038-4038</issn><eissn>2325-8012</eissn><coden>SECJAR</coden><abstract>Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings of others that consumer welfare and overall welfare are always higher under ad valorem taxation. However, ad valorem taxation generates larger profits (hence Pareto dominates) only when market demand is elastic, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit taxation in markets with inelastic demand. The effects on ad valorem Pareto dominance of within- and between-market substitutability, number of firms in the taxed market, and the level of taxation are also investigated. In the long run, an equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation reduces consumer price, which is welfare improving, but also reduces variety when market demand is elastic, which is welfare decreasing. Nonetheless, ad valorem welfare dominance still holds in the long run.</abstract><cop>Stillwater</cop><pub>Southern Economic Association</pub><doi>10.1002/j.2325-8012.2005.tb00713.x</doi><tpages>19</tpages></addata></record>
fulltext fulltext
identifier ISSN: 0038-4038
ispartof Southern economic journal, 2005-10, Vol.72 (2), p.463-481
issn 0038-4038
2325-8012
language eng
recordid cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_37707459
source Business Source Complete; Access via Wiley Online Library; JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing
subjects Ad valorem taxes
Consumer advertising
Consumers
Consumption
Economic aspects
Economic models
Economics
Efficiency
Elasticity of demand
Equilibrium
Excise taxes
Expenditures
Income taxes
Market
Market demand
Market prices
Oligopolies
Pareto efficiency
Pareto optimum
Price elasticity
Prices
Product differentiation
Profitability
Profits
Studies
Tax policy
Tax revenues
Taxation
Utility functions
Welfare
title Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation
url https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2024-12-05T01%3A28%3A26IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-gale_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Market%20Substitution%20and%20the%20Pareto%20Dominance%20of%20Ad%20Valorem%20Taxation&rft.jtitle=Southern%20economic%20journal&rft.au=Liu,%20Liqun&rft.date=2005-10&rft.volume=72&rft.issue=2&rft.spage=463&rft.epage=481&rft.pages=463-481&rft.issn=0038-4038&rft.eissn=2325-8012&rft.coden=SECJAR&rft_id=info:doi/10.1002/j.2325-8012.2005.tb00713.x&rft_dat=%3Cgale_proqu%3EA138225507%3C/gale_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=212142621&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_galeid=A138225507&rft_jstor_id=20062122&rfr_iscdi=true