Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation
Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Southern economic journal 2005-10, Vol.72 (2), p.463-481 |
---|---|
Hauptverfasser: | , |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 481 |
---|---|
container_issue | 2 |
container_start_page | 463 |
container_title | Southern economic journal |
container_volume | 72 |
creator | Liu, Liqun Saving, Thomas R. |
description | Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings of others that consumer welfare and overall welfare are always higher under ad valorem taxation. However, ad valorem taxation generates larger profits (hence Pareto dominates) only when market demand is elastic, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit taxation in markets with inelastic demand. The effects on ad valorem Pareto dominance of within- and between-market substitutability, number of firms in the taxed market, and the level of taxation are also investigated. In the long run, an equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation reduces consumer price, which is welfare improving, but also reduces variety when market demand is elastic, which is welfare decreasing. Nonetheless, ad valorem welfare dominance still holds in the long run. |
doi_str_mv | 10.1002/j.2325-8012.2005.tb00713.x |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>gale_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_37707459</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><galeid>A138225507</galeid><jstor_id>20062122</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>A138225507</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3933-21e6f4460375c245eb6ed4bfbf4b8b633a888669bb58e6d285a1c4370cccf7ae3</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqVkV1r1TAch4MoeJz7DmWgd615bXK8Oxw3X5hssOltSNN_ZmvbzCTFs29vaseQsRsppCF5nh9JfgidEFwRjOm7vqKMilJhQiuKsahSg7EkrDo8Q5uHredogzFTJc_DS_Qqxh5nmRCxQfuvJvyEVFzNTUxdmlPnp8JMbZF-QHFpAiRffPBjN5nJQuFdsWuL72bwAcbi2hzMwr9GL5wZIhzf_4_Qt7PT6_2n8vzi4-f97ry0bMtYSQnUjvMaMyks5QKaGlreuMbxRjU1Y0YpVdfbphEK6pYqYYjlTGJrrZMG2BF6u-beBv9rhpj02EULw2Am8HPUTEosudhm8OQR2Ps5TPlsmhJKOK0pyVC5QjdmAN1Nzqdg7A1MEPL9JnBdXt4RpigVAsvMV0_w-Wth7OyTwvtVsMHHGMDp29CNJtxpgvXSnu71UpFeKtJLe_q-PX3I8m6Vf-fUu_8w9dXF6Ze_85zxZs3oY_Lh3wzKsFy8_A6Usj8ihKui</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>212142621</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation</title><source>Business Source Complete</source><source>Access via Wiley Online Library</source><source>JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing</source><creator>Liu, Liqun ; Saving, Thomas R.</creator><creatorcontrib>Liu, Liqun ; Saving, Thomas R.</creatorcontrib><description>Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings of others that consumer welfare and overall welfare are always higher under ad valorem taxation. However, ad valorem taxation generates larger profits (hence Pareto dominates) only when market demand is elastic, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit taxation in markets with inelastic demand. The effects on ad valorem Pareto dominance of within- and between-market substitutability, number of firms in the taxed market, and the level of taxation are also investigated. In the long run, an equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation reduces consumer price, which is welfare improving, but also reduces variety when market demand is elastic, which is welfare decreasing. Nonetheless, ad valorem welfare dominance still holds in the long run.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0038-4038</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 2325-8012</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1002/j.2325-8012.2005.tb00713.x</identifier><identifier>CODEN: SECJAR</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Stillwater: Southern Economic Association</publisher><subject>Ad valorem taxes ; Consumer advertising ; Consumers ; Consumption ; Economic aspects ; Economic models ; Economics ; Efficiency ; Elasticity of demand ; Equilibrium ; Excise taxes ; Expenditures ; Income taxes ; Market ; Market demand ; Market prices ; Oligopolies ; Pareto efficiency ; Pareto optimum ; Price elasticity ; Prices ; Product differentiation ; Profitability ; Profits ; Studies ; Tax policy ; Tax revenues ; Taxation ; Utility functions ; Welfare</subject><ispartof>Southern economic journal, 2005-10, Vol.72 (2), p.463-481</ispartof><rights>Copyright 2005 Southern Economic Association</rights><rights>2005 Southern Economic Association</rights><rights>COPYRIGHT 2005 Southern Economic Association</rights><rights>(c)2005 Southern Economic Association</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3933-21e6f4460375c245eb6ed4bfbf4b8b633a888669bb58e6d285a1c4370cccf7ae3</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c3933-21e6f4460375c245eb6ed4bfbf4b8b633a888669bb58e6d285a1c4370cccf7ae3</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/20062122$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/20062122$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>315,782,786,805,1419,27931,27932,45581,45582,58024,58257</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Liu, Liqun</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Saving, Thomas R.</creatorcontrib><title>Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation</title><title>Southern economic journal</title><description>Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings of others that consumer welfare and overall welfare are always higher under ad valorem taxation. However, ad valorem taxation generates larger profits (hence Pareto dominates) only when market demand is elastic, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit taxation in markets with inelastic demand. The effects on ad valorem Pareto dominance of within- and between-market substitutability, number of firms in the taxed market, and the level of taxation are also investigated. In the long run, an equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation reduces consumer price, which is welfare improving, but also reduces variety when market demand is elastic, which is welfare decreasing. Nonetheless, ad valorem welfare dominance still holds in the long run.</description><subject>Ad valorem taxes</subject><subject>Consumer advertising</subject><subject>Consumers</subject><subject>Consumption</subject><subject>Economic aspects</subject><subject>Economic models</subject><subject>Economics</subject><subject>Efficiency</subject><subject>Elasticity of demand</subject><subject>Equilibrium</subject><subject>Excise taxes</subject><subject>Expenditures</subject><subject>Income taxes</subject><subject>Market</subject><subject>Market demand</subject><subject>Market prices</subject><subject>Oligopolies</subject><subject>Pareto efficiency</subject><subject>Pareto optimum</subject><subject>Price elasticity</subject><subject>Prices</subject><subject>Product differentiation</subject><subject>Profitability</subject><subject>Profits</subject><subject>Studies</subject><subject>Tax policy</subject><subject>Tax revenues</subject><subject>Taxation</subject><subject>Utility functions</subject><subject>Welfare</subject><issn>0038-4038</issn><issn>2325-8012</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2005</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>8G5</sourceid><sourceid>ABUWG</sourceid><sourceid>AFKRA</sourceid><sourceid>AZQEC</sourceid><sourceid>BEC</sourceid><sourceid>BENPR</sourceid><sourceid>CCPQU</sourceid><sourceid>DWQXO</sourceid><sourceid>GNUQQ</sourceid><sourceid>GUQSH</sourceid><sourceid>M2O</sourceid><recordid>eNqVkV1r1TAch4MoeJz7DmWgd615bXK8Oxw3X5hssOltSNN_ZmvbzCTFs29vaseQsRsppCF5nh9JfgidEFwRjOm7vqKMilJhQiuKsahSg7EkrDo8Q5uHredogzFTJc_DS_Qqxh5nmRCxQfuvJvyEVFzNTUxdmlPnp8JMbZF-QHFpAiRffPBjN5nJQuFdsWuL72bwAcbi2hzMwr9GL5wZIhzf_4_Qt7PT6_2n8vzi4-f97ry0bMtYSQnUjvMaMyks5QKaGlreuMbxRjU1Y0YpVdfbphEK6pYqYYjlTGJrrZMG2BF6u-beBv9rhpj02EULw2Am8HPUTEosudhm8OQR2Ps5TPlsmhJKOK0pyVC5QjdmAN1Nzqdg7A1MEPL9JnBdXt4RpigVAsvMV0_w-Wth7OyTwvtVsMHHGMDp29CNJtxpgvXSnu71UpFeKtJLe_q-PX3I8m6Vf-fUu_8w9dXF6Ze_85zxZs3oY_Lh3wzKsFy8_A6Usj8ihKui</recordid><startdate>200510</startdate><enddate>200510</enddate><creator>Liu, Liqun</creator><creator>Saving, Thomas R.</creator><general>Southern Economic Association</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>0-V</scope><scope>0U~</scope><scope>1-H</scope><scope>3V.</scope><scope>4S-</scope><scope>4T-</scope><scope>7WY</scope><scope>7WZ</scope><scope>7XB</scope><scope>87Z</scope><scope>88J</scope><scope>8AO</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>8FK</scope><scope>8FL</scope><scope>8G5</scope><scope>ABUWG</scope><scope>AFKRA</scope><scope>ALSLI</scope><scope>AZQEC</scope><scope>BEC</scope><scope>BENPR</scope><scope>BEZIV</scope><scope>CCPQU</scope><scope>DWQXO</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>FRNLG</scope><scope>F~G</scope><scope>GNUQQ</scope><scope>GUQSH</scope><scope>JBE</scope><scope>K60</scope><scope>K6~</scope><scope>L.-</scope><scope>L.0</scope><scope>M0C</scope><scope>M2O</scope><scope>M2R</scope><scope>MBDVC</scope><scope>PQBIZ</scope><scope>PQBZA</scope><scope>PQEST</scope><scope>PQQKQ</scope><scope>PQUKI</scope><scope>PRINS</scope><scope>Q9U</scope><scope>S0X</scope></search><sort><creationdate>200510</creationdate><title>Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation</title><author>Liu, Liqun ; Saving, Thomas R.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c3933-21e6f4460375c245eb6ed4bfbf4b8b633a888669bb58e6d285a1c4370cccf7ae3</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2005</creationdate><topic>Ad valorem taxes</topic><topic>Consumer advertising</topic><topic>Consumers</topic><topic>Consumption</topic><topic>Economic aspects</topic><topic>Economic models</topic><topic>Economics</topic><topic>Efficiency</topic><topic>Elasticity of demand</topic><topic>Equilibrium</topic><topic>Excise taxes</topic><topic>Expenditures</topic><topic>Income taxes</topic><topic>Market</topic><topic>Market demand</topic><topic>Market prices</topic><topic>Oligopolies</topic><topic>Pareto efficiency</topic><topic>Pareto optimum</topic><topic>Price elasticity</topic><topic>Prices</topic><topic>Product differentiation</topic><topic>Profitability</topic><topic>Profits</topic><topic>Studies</topic><topic>Tax policy</topic><topic>Tax revenues</topic><topic>Taxation</topic><topic>Utility functions</topic><topic>Welfare</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Liu, Liqun</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Saving, Thomas R.</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>ProQuest Social Sciences Premium Collection</collection><collection>Global News & ABI/Inform Professional</collection><collection>Trade PRO</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Corporate)</collection><collection>BPIR.com Limited</collection><collection>Docstoc</collection><collection>Access via ABI/INFORM (ProQuest)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (PDF only)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>Social Science Database (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Pharma Collection</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni) (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Collection (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>Research Library (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central UK/Ireland</collection><collection>Social Science Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Essentials</collection><collection>eLibrary</collection><collection>ProQuest Central</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest One Community College</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Korea</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection (Alumni)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (Corporate)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Student</collection><collection>Research Library Prep</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Professional Advanced</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Professional Standard</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global</collection><collection>Research Library</collection><collection>Social Science Database</collection><collection>Research Library (Corporate)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business (Alumni)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic Eastern Edition (DO NOT USE)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic UKI Edition</collection><collection>ProQuest Central China</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Basic</collection><collection>SIRS Editorial</collection><jtitle>Southern economic journal</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Liu, Liqun</au><au>Saving, Thomas R.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation</atitle><jtitle>Southern economic journal</jtitle><date>2005-10</date><risdate>2005</risdate><volume>72</volume><issue>2</issue><spage>463</spage><epage>481</epage><pages>463-481</pages><issn>0038-4038</issn><eissn>2325-8012</eissn><coden>SECJAR</coden><abstract>Based on product homogeneity and Cournot competition, past literature has uniformly shown that ad valorem taxation welfare dominates unit taxation in noncompetitive markets. This paper allows goods in a market to be heterogeneous and firms to be Bertrand competing. We confirm the short-run findings of others that consumer welfare and overall welfare are always higher under ad valorem taxation. However, ad valorem taxation generates larger profits (hence Pareto dominates) only when market demand is elastic, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit taxation in markets with inelastic demand. The effects on ad valorem Pareto dominance of within- and between-market substitutability, number of firms in the taxed market, and the level of taxation are also investigated. In the long run, an equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation reduces consumer price, which is welfare improving, but also reduces variety when market demand is elastic, which is welfare decreasing. Nonetheless, ad valorem welfare dominance still holds in the long run.</abstract><cop>Stillwater</cop><pub>Southern Economic Association</pub><doi>10.1002/j.2325-8012.2005.tb00713.x</doi><tpages>19</tpages></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0038-4038 |
ispartof | Southern economic journal, 2005-10, Vol.72 (2), p.463-481 |
issn | 0038-4038 2325-8012 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_37707459 |
source | Business Source Complete; Access via Wiley Online Library; JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing |
subjects | Ad valorem taxes Consumer advertising Consumers Consumption Economic aspects Economic models Economics Efficiency Elasticity of demand Equilibrium Excise taxes Expenditures Income taxes Market Market demand Market prices Oligopolies Pareto efficiency Pareto optimum Price elasticity Prices Product differentiation Profitability Profits Studies Tax policy Tax revenues Taxation Utility functions Welfare |
title | Market Substitution and the Pareto Dominance of Ad Valorem Taxation |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2024-12-05T01%3A28%3A26IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-gale_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Market%20Substitution%20and%20the%20Pareto%20Dominance%20of%20Ad%20Valorem%20Taxation&rft.jtitle=Southern%20economic%20journal&rft.au=Liu,%20Liqun&rft.date=2005-10&rft.volume=72&rft.issue=2&rft.spage=463&rft.epage=481&rft.pages=463-481&rft.issn=0038-4038&rft.eissn=2325-8012&rft.coden=SECJAR&rft_id=info:doi/10.1002/j.2325-8012.2005.tb00713.x&rft_dat=%3Cgale_proqu%3EA138225507%3C/gale_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=212142621&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_galeid=A138225507&rft_jstor_id=20062122&rfr_iscdi=true |