How limiting deceptive practices harms consumers
There are two competing sellers of an experience good, one offers high quality, one low. The low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising, potentially fooling a buyer into thinking the product is better than it is. Although deceptive advertising might seem to harm the buyer, we show that h...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | The Rand journal of economics 2015-09, Vol.46 (3), p.611-624 |
---|---|
Hauptverfasser: | , , |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 624 |
---|---|
container_issue | 3 |
container_start_page | 611 |
container_title | The Rand journal of economics |
container_volume | 46 |
creator | Piccolo, Salvatore Tedeschi, Piero Ursino, Giovanni |
description | There are two competing sellers of an experience good, one offers high quality, one low. The low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising, potentially fooling a buyer into thinking the product is better than it is. Although deceptive advertising might seem to harm the buyer, we show that he could be better off when the low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising than not. We characterize the optimal deterrence rule that a regulatory agency seeking to punish deceptive practices should adopt. We show that greater protection against deceptive practices does not necessarily improve the buyer welfare. |
doi_str_mv | 10.1111/1756-2171.12099 |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>jstor_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_1704340046</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><jstor_id>43895607</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>43895607</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c5149-cc8fe16ca49efba36500a36bf6ee3ca9302e6b48eefb2457c3ad8a5923d15dc83</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqFkM1LwzAYh4MoOKdnT0LBi5fOfKc9jvkJY4pMPIYse6uZ7TqT1ul_b2Z1By--hwTye56X8EPomOABiXNOlJApJYoMCMV5voN625dd1MOKk1RSSfbRQQgLHIcq2kP4pl4npatc45bPyRwsrBr3DsnKG9s4CyF5Mb4Kia2Xoa3Ah0O0V5gywNHP3UePV5fT0U06vru-HQ3HqRWE56m1WQFEWsNzKGaGSYFxPGeFBGDW5AxTkDOeQUwpF8oyM8-MyCmbEzG3Geujs27vytdvLYRGVy5YKEuzhLoNmijMGceYy4ie_kEXdeuX8XeRogIziQWJ1HlHWV-H4KHQK-8q4z81wXrToN70pTd96e8GoyE7Y-1K-PwP1w_DycWveNKJi9DUfityluVCYhXztMtdaOBjmxv_qqViSuinybW-nwo6YfcTTdgXydeKew</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1725036051</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>How limiting deceptive practices harms consumers</title><source>EBSCOhost Business Source Complete</source><source>Access via Wiley Online Library</source><source>JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing</source><creator>Piccolo, Salvatore ; Tedeschi, Piero ; Ursino, Giovanni</creator><creatorcontrib>Piccolo, Salvatore ; Tedeschi, Piero ; Ursino, Giovanni</creatorcontrib><description>There are two competing sellers of an experience good, one offers high quality, one low. The low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising, potentially fooling a buyer into thinking the product is better than it is. Although deceptive advertising might seem to harm the buyer, we show that he could be better off when the low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising than not. We characterize the optimal deterrence rule that a regulatory agency seeking to punish deceptive practices should adopt. We show that greater protection against deceptive practices does not necessarily improve the buyer welfare.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0741-6261</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1756-2171</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1111/1756-2171.12099</identifier><identifier>CODEN: RJECEA</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Santa Monica: Blackwell Publishing Ltd</publisher><subject>Advertising ; Buyers surplus ; Consumer advertising ; Consumer information ; Consumer prices ; Consumers ; Coordinate systems ; Deceit ; Deceptive advertising ; Deterrence ; Economic analysis ; Equilibrium prices ; False advertising ; Goods ; Monopoly ; Sales management ; Studies ; Welfare</subject><ispartof>The Rand journal of economics, 2015-09, Vol.46 (3), p.611-624</ispartof><rights>2015 The RAND Corporation</rights><rights>2015, RAND.</rights><rights>Copyright Rand Corporation Fall 2015</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><oa>free_for_read</oa><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c5149-cc8fe16ca49efba36500a36bf6ee3ca9302e6b48eefb2457c3ad8a5923d15dc83</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c5149-cc8fe16ca49efba36500a36bf6ee3ca9302e6b48eefb2457c3ad8a5923d15dc83</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/43895607$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/43895607$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,780,784,803,1417,27924,27925,45574,45575,58017,58250</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Piccolo, Salvatore</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Tedeschi, Piero</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Ursino, Giovanni</creatorcontrib><title>How limiting deceptive practices harms consumers</title><title>The Rand journal of economics</title><addtitle>The RAND Journal of Economics</addtitle><description>There are two competing sellers of an experience good, one offers high quality, one low. The low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising, potentially fooling a buyer into thinking the product is better than it is. Although deceptive advertising might seem to harm the buyer, we show that he could be better off when the low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising than not. We characterize the optimal deterrence rule that a regulatory agency seeking to punish deceptive practices should adopt. We show that greater protection against deceptive practices does not necessarily improve the buyer welfare.</description><subject>Advertising</subject><subject>Buyers surplus</subject><subject>Consumer advertising</subject><subject>Consumer information</subject><subject>Consumer prices</subject><subject>Consumers</subject><subject>Coordinate systems</subject><subject>Deceit</subject><subject>Deceptive advertising</subject><subject>Deterrence</subject><subject>Economic analysis</subject><subject>Equilibrium prices</subject><subject>False advertising</subject><subject>Goods</subject><subject>Monopoly</subject><subject>Sales management</subject><subject>Studies</subject><subject>Welfare</subject><issn>0741-6261</issn><issn>1756-2171</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2015</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><recordid>eNqFkM1LwzAYh4MoOKdnT0LBi5fOfKc9jvkJY4pMPIYse6uZ7TqT1ul_b2Z1By--hwTye56X8EPomOABiXNOlJApJYoMCMV5voN625dd1MOKk1RSSfbRQQgLHIcq2kP4pl4npatc45bPyRwsrBr3DsnKG9s4CyF5Mb4Kia2Xoa3Ah0O0V5gywNHP3UePV5fT0U06vru-HQ3HqRWE56m1WQFEWsNzKGaGSYFxPGeFBGDW5AxTkDOeQUwpF8oyM8-MyCmbEzG3Geujs27vytdvLYRGVy5YKEuzhLoNmijMGceYy4ie_kEXdeuX8XeRogIziQWJ1HlHWV-H4KHQK-8q4z81wXrToN70pTd96e8GoyE7Y-1K-PwP1w_DycWveNKJi9DUfityluVCYhXztMtdaOBjmxv_qqViSuinybW-nwo6YfcTTdgXydeKew</recordid><startdate>20150901</startdate><enddate>20150901</enddate><creator>Piccolo, Salvatore</creator><creator>Tedeschi, Piero</creator><creator>Ursino, Giovanni</creator><general>Blackwell Publishing Ltd</general><general>Wiley Periodicals, Inc</general><general>Rand Corporation</general><scope>BSCLL</scope><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope><scope>K9.</scope></search><sort><creationdate>20150901</creationdate><title>How limiting deceptive practices harms consumers</title><author>Piccolo, Salvatore ; Tedeschi, Piero ; Ursino, Giovanni</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c5149-cc8fe16ca49efba36500a36bf6ee3ca9302e6b48eefb2457c3ad8a5923d15dc83</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2015</creationdate><topic>Advertising</topic><topic>Buyers surplus</topic><topic>Consumer advertising</topic><topic>Consumer information</topic><topic>Consumer prices</topic><topic>Consumers</topic><topic>Coordinate systems</topic><topic>Deceit</topic><topic>Deceptive advertising</topic><topic>Deterrence</topic><topic>Economic analysis</topic><topic>Equilibrium prices</topic><topic>False advertising</topic><topic>Goods</topic><topic>Monopoly</topic><topic>Sales management</topic><topic>Studies</topic><topic>Welfare</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Piccolo, Salvatore</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Tedeschi, Piero</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Ursino, Giovanni</creatorcontrib><collection>Istex</collection><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>ProQuest Health & Medical Complete (Alumni)</collection><jtitle>The Rand journal of economics</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Piccolo, Salvatore</au><au>Tedeschi, Piero</au><au>Ursino, Giovanni</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>How limiting deceptive practices harms consumers</atitle><jtitle>The Rand journal of economics</jtitle><addtitle>The RAND Journal of Economics</addtitle><date>2015-09-01</date><risdate>2015</risdate><volume>46</volume><issue>3</issue><spage>611</spage><epage>624</epage><pages>611-624</pages><issn>0741-6261</issn><eissn>1756-2171</eissn><coden>RJECEA</coden><abstract>There are two competing sellers of an experience good, one offers high quality, one low. The low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising, potentially fooling a buyer into thinking the product is better than it is. Although deceptive advertising might seem to harm the buyer, we show that he could be better off when the low-quality seller can engage in deceptive advertising than not. We characterize the optimal deterrence rule that a regulatory agency seeking to punish deceptive practices should adopt. We show that greater protection against deceptive practices does not necessarily improve the buyer welfare.</abstract><cop>Santa Monica</cop><pub>Blackwell Publishing Ltd</pub><doi>10.1111/1756-2171.12099</doi><tpages>14</tpages><oa>free_for_read</oa></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0741-6261 |
ispartof | The Rand journal of economics, 2015-09, Vol.46 (3), p.611-624 |
issn | 0741-6261 1756-2171 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_1704340046 |
source | EBSCOhost Business Source Complete; Access via Wiley Online Library; JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing |
subjects | Advertising Buyers surplus Consumer advertising Consumer information Consumer prices Consumers Coordinate systems Deceit Deceptive advertising Deterrence Economic analysis Equilibrium prices False advertising Goods Monopoly Sales management Studies Welfare |
title | How limiting deceptive practices harms consumers |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2024-12-19T03%3A03%3A27IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-jstor_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=How%20limiting%20deceptive%20practices%20harms%20consumers&rft.jtitle=The%20Rand%20journal%20of%20economics&rft.au=Piccolo,%20Salvatore&rft.date=2015-09-01&rft.volume=46&rft.issue=3&rft.spage=611&rft.epage=624&rft.pages=611-624&rft.issn=0741-6261&rft.eissn=1756-2171&rft.coden=RJECEA&rft_id=info:doi/10.1111/1756-2171.12099&rft_dat=%3Cjstor_proqu%3E43895607%3C/jstor_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1725036051&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_jstor_id=43895607&rfr_iscdi=true |