The bears are right: Why cap-and-trade yields greater emission reductions than expected, and what that means for climate policy
Cap-and-trade, a regulatory instrument widely used to constrain greenhouse gas and other pollution, has recently been criticized for producing only small amounts of intended emission reductions. This paper looks at the empirical record of cap-and-trade since the beginning in 1995, and shows that emi...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Climatic change 2014-12, Vol.127 (3-4), p.447-461 |
---|---|
1. Verfasser: | |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 461 |
---|---|
container_issue | 3-4 |
container_start_page | 447 |
container_title | Climatic change |
container_volume | 127 |
creator | Tvinnereim, Endre |
description | Cap-and-trade, a regulatory instrument widely used to constrain greenhouse gas and other pollution, has recently been criticized for producing only small amounts of intended emission reductions. This paper looks at the empirical record of cap-and-trade since the beginning in 1995, and shows that emission targets have almost always been easier and cheaper to reach than expected. The five main reasons are generous targets, changes in economic output, fuel price movements, innovation, and complementary emission reduction policies. Overall, this failure to predict mitigation potentials may relate to a psychological “end of history bias,” whereby policymakers, industry, and analysts think that less change will happen in the future than has demonstrably happened in the past. Consequently, more abatement is possible and at lower costs than generally thought, rendering the prices of emission permits hard to predict. For climate research, the findings imply that emission scenarios assuming ever-increasing pollution prices may benefit from integrating recent experience with cap-and-trade regulations. In policy terms, mechanisms such as floor prices need to be considered to guarantee emission reductions under uncertainty. |
doi_str_mv | 10.1007/s10584-014-1282-1 |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>proquest_cross</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_1651391313</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><sourcerecordid>3506219541</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c525t-8d681d2a1aa1a3c2535c2402b8cdc18a31c8a1d81fd6d3799abec0783975b62b3</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqNkV1rFTEQhoMoeKz9Ab0LlEIvjGaS_ch6J0WtUPCm4mWYTWbPbtmzu01yqOfKv26WU4oIBWFghuSZl5l5GTsD-R6krD9EkKUphIRCgDJKwAu2gbLWAgojX7KNhKoUUsrmNXsT491a1arasN-3PfGWMESOgXgYtn36yH_2B-5wETh5kQJ64oeBRh_5NhAmCpx2Q4zDPPFAfu9SriJPPU6cfi3kEvl3PPfyhx7T-p74jjAj3Ry4G4dd1uDLPA7u8Ja96nCMdPqYT9iPL59vr67Fzfev364-3QhXqjIJ4ysDXiFgDu1UqUunCqla47wDgxqcQfAGOl95XTcNtuRkbXRTl22lWn3CLo-6S5jv9xSTzRs4GkecaN5Hm88DugEN-j_QQlV5ggIyev4Pejfvw5QXyZSqK13rymQKjpQLc4yBOruEfINwsCDt6p49umeze3Z1z67KF4_KGB2OXcDJDfGpUTXZQAMrp45czF_TlsJfEzwr_gcJqqlV</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1627637368</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>The bears are right: Why cap-and-trade yields greater emission reductions than expected, and what that means for climate policy</title><source>SpringerNature Journals</source><creator>Tvinnereim, Endre</creator><creatorcontrib>Tvinnereim, Endre</creatorcontrib><description>Cap-and-trade, a regulatory instrument widely used to constrain greenhouse gas and other pollution, has recently been criticized for producing only small amounts of intended emission reductions. This paper looks at the empirical record of cap-and-trade since the beginning in 1995, and shows that emission targets have almost always been easier and cheaper to reach than expected. The five main reasons are generous targets, changes in economic output, fuel price movements, innovation, and complementary emission reduction policies. Overall, this failure to predict mitigation potentials may relate to a psychological “end of history bias,” whereby policymakers, industry, and analysts think that less change will happen in the future than has demonstrably happened in the past. Consequently, more abatement is possible and at lower costs than generally thought, rendering the prices of emission permits hard to predict. For climate research, the findings imply that emission scenarios assuming ever-increasing pollution prices may benefit from integrating recent experience with cap-and-trade regulations. In policy terms, mechanisms such as floor prices need to be considered to guarantee emission reductions under uncertainty.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0165-0009</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1573-1480</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1007/s10584-014-1282-1</identifier><identifier>CODEN: CLCHDX</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands</publisher><subject>Air pollution ; Atmospheric Sciences ; Carbon ; Clean technology ; Climate ; Climate change ; Climate Change/Climate Change Impacts ; Climate policy ; Climate science ; Climatology. Bioclimatology. Climate change ; Compliance ; Costs ; Earth and Environmental Science ; Earth Sciences ; Earth, ocean, space ; Economics ; Emission ; Emission standards ; Emissions ; Emissions control ; Emissions trading ; Environmental policy ; Exact sciences and technology ; External geophysics ; Free trade ; Greenhouse effect ; Greenhouse gases ; Kyoto Protocol ; Meteorology ; Policies ; Pollution ; Pollution abatement ; Price levels ; Reduction</subject><ispartof>Climatic change, 2014-12, Vol.127 (3-4), p.447-461</ispartof><rights>The Author(s) 2014</rights><rights>2015 INIST-CNRS</rights><rights>Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2014</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><oa>free_for_read</oa><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c525t-8d681d2a1aa1a3c2535c2402b8cdc18a31c8a1d81fd6d3799abec0783975b62b3</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c525t-8d681d2a1aa1a3c2535c2402b8cdc18a31c8a1d81fd6d3799abec0783975b62b3</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://link.springer.com/content/pdf/10.1007/s10584-014-1282-1$$EPDF$$P50$$Gspringer$$Hfree_for_read</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://link.springer.com/10.1007/s10584-014-1282-1$$EHTML$$P50$$Gspringer$$Hfree_for_read</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,780,784,27924,27925,41488,42557,51319</link.rule.ids><backlink>$$Uhttp://pascal-francis.inist.fr/vibad/index.php?action=getRecordDetail&idt=29009811$$DView record in Pascal Francis$$Hfree_for_read</backlink></links><search><creatorcontrib>Tvinnereim, Endre</creatorcontrib><title>The bears are right: Why cap-and-trade yields greater emission reductions than expected, and what that means for climate policy</title><title>Climatic change</title><addtitle>Climatic Change</addtitle><description>Cap-and-trade, a regulatory instrument widely used to constrain greenhouse gas and other pollution, has recently been criticized for producing only small amounts of intended emission reductions. This paper looks at the empirical record of cap-and-trade since the beginning in 1995, and shows that emission targets have almost always been easier and cheaper to reach than expected. The five main reasons are generous targets, changes in economic output, fuel price movements, innovation, and complementary emission reduction policies. Overall, this failure to predict mitigation potentials may relate to a psychological “end of history bias,” whereby policymakers, industry, and analysts think that less change will happen in the future than has demonstrably happened in the past. Consequently, more abatement is possible and at lower costs than generally thought, rendering the prices of emission permits hard to predict. For climate research, the findings imply that emission scenarios assuming ever-increasing pollution prices may benefit from integrating recent experience with cap-and-trade regulations. In policy terms, mechanisms such as floor prices need to be considered to guarantee emission reductions under uncertainty.</description><subject>Air pollution</subject><subject>Atmospheric Sciences</subject><subject>Carbon</subject><subject>Clean technology</subject><subject>Climate</subject><subject>Climate change</subject><subject>Climate Change/Climate Change Impacts</subject><subject>Climate policy</subject><subject>Climate science</subject><subject>Climatology. Bioclimatology. Climate change</subject><subject>Compliance</subject><subject>Costs</subject><subject>Earth and Environmental Science</subject><subject>Earth Sciences</subject><subject>Earth, ocean, space</subject><subject>Economics</subject><subject>Emission</subject><subject>Emission standards</subject><subject>Emissions</subject><subject>Emissions control</subject><subject>Emissions trading</subject><subject>Environmental policy</subject><subject>Exact sciences and technology</subject><subject>External geophysics</subject><subject>Free trade</subject><subject>Greenhouse effect</subject><subject>Greenhouse gases</subject><subject>Kyoto Protocol</subject><subject>Meteorology</subject><subject>Policies</subject><subject>Pollution</subject><subject>Pollution abatement</subject><subject>Price levels</subject><subject>Reduction</subject><issn>0165-0009</issn><issn>1573-1480</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2014</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>C6C</sourceid><sourceid>8G5</sourceid><sourceid>ABUWG</sourceid><sourceid>AFKRA</sourceid><sourceid>AZQEC</sourceid><sourceid>BENPR</sourceid><sourceid>CCPQU</sourceid><sourceid>DWQXO</sourceid><sourceid>GNUQQ</sourceid><sourceid>GUQSH</sourceid><sourceid>M2O</sourceid><recordid>eNqNkV1rFTEQhoMoeKz9Ab0LlEIvjGaS_ch6J0WtUPCm4mWYTWbPbtmzu01yqOfKv26WU4oIBWFghuSZl5l5GTsD-R6krD9EkKUphIRCgDJKwAu2gbLWAgojX7KNhKoUUsrmNXsT491a1arasN-3PfGWMESOgXgYtn36yH_2B-5wETh5kQJ64oeBRh_5NhAmCpx2Q4zDPPFAfu9SriJPPU6cfi3kEvl3PPfyhx7T-p74jjAj3Ry4G4dd1uDLPA7u8Ja96nCMdPqYT9iPL59vr67Fzfev364-3QhXqjIJ4ysDXiFgDu1UqUunCqla47wDgxqcQfAGOl95XTcNtuRkbXRTl22lWn3CLo-6S5jv9xSTzRs4GkecaN5Hm88DugEN-j_QQlV5ggIyev4Pejfvw5QXyZSqK13rymQKjpQLc4yBOruEfINwsCDt6p49umeze3Z1z67KF4_KGB2OXcDJDfGpUTXZQAMrp45czF_TlsJfEzwr_gcJqqlV</recordid><startdate>20141201</startdate><enddate>20141201</enddate><creator>Tvinnereim, Endre</creator><general>Springer Netherlands</general><general>Springer</general><general>Springer Nature B.V</general><scope>C6C</scope><scope>IQODW</scope><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>3V.</scope><scope>7ST</scope><scope>7TG</scope><scope>7TN</scope><scope>7UA</scope><scope>7WY</scope><scope>7WZ</scope><scope>7XB</scope><scope>87Z</scope><scope>88I</scope><scope>8FD</scope><scope>8FE</scope><scope>8FG</scope><scope>8FK</scope><scope>8FL</scope><scope>8G5</scope><scope>ABJCF</scope><scope>ABUWG</scope><scope>AFKRA</scope><scope>ARAPS</scope><scope>ATCPS</scope><scope>AZQEC</scope><scope>BENPR</scope><scope>BEZIV</scope><scope>BGLVJ</scope><scope>BHPHI</scope><scope>BKSAR</scope><scope>C1K</scope><scope>CCPQU</scope><scope>DWQXO</scope><scope>F1W</scope><scope>F28</scope><scope>FR3</scope><scope>FRNLG</scope><scope>F~G</scope><scope>GNUQQ</scope><scope>GUQSH</scope><scope>H97</scope><scope>HCIFZ</scope><scope>K60</scope><scope>K6~</scope><scope>KL.</scope><scope>KR7</scope><scope>L.-</scope><scope>L.G</scope><scope>L6V</scope><scope>M0C</scope><scope>M2O</scope><scope>M2P</scope><scope>M7S</scope><scope>MBDVC</scope><scope>P5Z</scope><scope>P62</scope><scope>PATMY</scope><scope>PCBAR</scope><scope>PQBIZ</scope><scope>PQBZA</scope><scope>PQEST</scope><scope>PQQKQ</scope><scope>PQUKI</scope><scope>PTHSS</scope><scope>PYCSY</scope><scope>Q9U</scope><scope>R05</scope><scope>SOI</scope><scope>7TV</scope><scope>7U6</scope><scope>7SU</scope></search><sort><creationdate>20141201</creationdate><title>The bears are right: Why cap-and-trade yields greater emission reductions than expected, and what that means for climate policy</title><author>Tvinnereim, Endre</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c525t-8d681d2a1aa1a3c2535c2402b8cdc18a31c8a1d81fd6d3799abec0783975b62b3</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2014</creationdate><topic>Air pollution</topic><topic>Atmospheric Sciences</topic><topic>Carbon</topic><topic>Clean technology</topic><topic>Climate</topic><topic>Climate change</topic><topic>Climate Change/Climate Change Impacts</topic><topic>Climate policy</topic><topic>Climate science</topic><topic>Climatology. Bioclimatology. Climate change</topic><topic>Compliance</topic><topic>Costs</topic><topic>Earth and Environmental Science</topic><topic>Earth Sciences</topic><topic>Earth, ocean, space</topic><topic>Economics</topic><topic>Emission</topic><topic>Emission standards</topic><topic>Emissions</topic><topic>Emissions control</topic><topic>Emissions trading</topic><topic>Environmental policy</topic><topic>Exact sciences and technology</topic><topic>External geophysics</topic><topic>Free trade</topic><topic>Greenhouse effect</topic><topic>Greenhouse gases</topic><topic>Kyoto Protocol</topic><topic>Meteorology</topic><topic>Policies</topic><topic>Pollution</topic><topic>Pollution abatement</topic><topic>Price levels</topic><topic>Reduction</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Tvinnereim, Endre</creatorcontrib><collection>Springer Nature OA Free Journals</collection><collection>Pascal-Francis</collection><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Corporate)</collection><collection>Environment Abstracts</collection><collection>Meteorological & Geoastrophysical Abstracts</collection><collection>Oceanic Abstracts</collection><collection>Water Resources Abstracts</collection><collection>Access via ABI/INFORM (ProQuest)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (PDF only)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>Science Database (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>Technology Research Database</collection><collection>ProQuest SciTech Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Technology Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni) (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Collection (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>Research Library (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>Materials Science & Engineering Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central UK/Ireland</collection><collection>Advanced Technologies & Aerospace Collection</collection><collection>Agricultural & Environmental Science Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Essentials</collection><collection>ProQuest Central</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection</collection><collection>Technology Collection</collection><collection>Natural Science Collection</collection><collection>Earth, Atmospheric & Aquatic Science Collection</collection><collection>Environmental Sciences and Pollution Management</collection><collection>ProQuest One Community College</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Korea</collection><collection>ASFA: Aquatic Sciences and Fisheries Abstracts</collection><collection>ANTE: Abstracts in New Technology & Engineering</collection><collection>Engineering Research Database</collection><collection>Business Premium Collection (Alumni)</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global (Corporate)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Student</collection><collection>Research Library Prep</collection><collection>Aquatic Science & Fisheries Abstracts (ASFA) 3: Aquatic Pollution & Environmental Quality</collection><collection>SciTech Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Business Collection</collection><collection>Meteorological & Geoastrophysical Abstracts - Academic</collection><collection>Civil Engineering Abstracts</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Professional Advanced</collection><collection>Aquatic Science & Fisheries Abstracts (ASFA) Professional</collection><collection>ProQuest Engineering Collection</collection><collection>ABI/INFORM Global</collection><collection>Research Library</collection><collection>Science Database</collection><collection>Engineering Database</collection><collection>Research Library (Corporate)</collection><collection>Advanced Technologies & Aerospace Database</collection><collection>ProQuest Advanced Technologies & Aerospace Collection</collection><collection>Environmental Science Database</collection><collection>Earth, Atmospheric & Aquatic Science Database</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business</collection><collection>ProQuest One Business (Alumni)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic Eastern Edition (DO NOT USE)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic UKI Edition</collection><collection>Engineering Collection</collection><collection>Environmental Science Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Basic</collection><collection>University of Michigan</collection><collection>Environment Abstracts</collection><collection>Pollution Abstracts</collection><collection>Sustainability Science Abstracts</collection><collection>Environmental Engineering Abstracts</collection><jtitle>Climatic change</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Tvinnereim, Endre</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>The bears are right: Why cap-and-trade yields greater emission reductions than expected, and what that means for climate policy</atitle><jtitle>Climatic change</jtitle><stitle>Climatic Change</stitle><date>2014-12-01</date><risdate>2014</risdate><volume>127</volume><issue>3-4</issue><spage>447</spage><epage>461</epage><pages>447-461</pages><issn>0165-0009</issn><eissn>1573-1480</eissn><coden>CLCHDX</coden><abstract>Cap-and-trade, a regulatory instrument widely used to constrain greenhouse gas and other pollution, has recently been criticized for producing only small amounts of intended emission reductions. This paper looks at the empirical record of cap-and-trade since the beginning in 1995, and shows that emission targets have almost always been easier and cheaper to reach than expected. The five main reasons are generous targets, changes in economic output, fuel price movements, innovation, and complementary emission reduction policies. Overall, this failure to predict mitigation potentials may relate to a psychological “end of history bias,” whereby policymakers, industry, and analysts think that less change will happen in the future than has demonstrably happened in the past. Consequently, more abatement is possible and at lower costs than generally thought, rendering the prices of emission permits hard to predict. For climate research, the findings imply that emission scenarios assuming ever-increasing pollution prices may benefit from integrating recent experience with cap-and-trade regulations. In policy terms, mechanisms such as floor prices need to be considered to guarantee emission reductions under uncertainty.</abstract><cop>Dordrecht</cop><pub>Springer Netherlands</pub><doi>10.1007/s10584-014-1282-1</doi><tpages>15</tpages><oa>free_for_read</oa></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0165-0009 |
ispartof | Climatic change, 2014-12, Vol.127 (3-4), p.447-461 |
issn | 0165-0009 1573-1480 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_1651391313 |
source | SpringerNature Journals |
subjects | Air pollution Atmospheric Sciences Carbon Clean technology Climate Climate change Climate Change/Climate Change Impacts Climate policy Climate science Climatology. Bioclimatology. Climate change Compliance Costs Earth and Environmental Science Earth Sciences Earth, ocean, space Economics Emission Emission standards Emissions Emissions control Emissions trading Environmental policy Exact sciences and technology External geophysics Free trade Greenhouse effect Greenhouse gases Kyoto Protocol Meteorology Policies Pollution Pollution abatement Price levels Reduction |
title | The bears are right: Why cap-and-trade yields greater emission reductions than expected, and what that means for climate policy |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2024-12-29T16%3A31%3A13IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-proquest_cross&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=The%20bears%20are%20right:%20Why%20cap-and-trade%20yields%20greater%20emission%20reductions%20than%20expected,%20and%20what%20that%20means%20for%20climate%20policy&rft.jtitle=Climatic%20change&rft.au=Tvinnereim,%20Endre&rft.date=2014-12-01&rft.volume=127&rft.issue=3-4&rft.spage=447&rft.epage=461&rft.pages=447-461&rft.issn=0165-0009&rft.eissn=1573-1480&rft.coden=CLCHDX&rft_id=info:doi/10.1007/s10584-014-1282-1&rft_dat=%3Cproquest_cross%3E3506219541%3C/proquest_cross%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1627637368&rft_id=info:pmid/&rfr_iscdi=true |