The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State

In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology,...

Ausführliche Beschreibung

Gespeichert in:
Bibliographische Detailangaben
Veröffentlicht in:Environment and history 2012-02, Vol.18 (1), p.125-150
1. Verfasser: MacDonald, Graham A.
Format: Artikel
Sprache:eng
Schlagworte:
Online-Zugang:Volltext
Tags: Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
container_end_page 150
container_issue 1
container_start_page 125
container_title Environment and history
container_volume 18
creator MacDonald, Graham A.
description In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology, hostile to mass machine production. Mumford was not the first to draw attention to the relevance of Ruskin for developing environmental and urban planning theories. Despite Ruskin's frequent castigation of John Stuart Mill's ideas on political economy, and others of the eighteenth century 'classical school' of political economy, he shared a good deal with them. With Mill he displayed a preference for governments empowered to exercise legislative control in the imposition of limits to growth and in safeguarding worker interests. Notions of the 'stationary state' can be found in the mature writings of Malthus, Mill and Ruskin. In Ruskin's case, however, his views were shaped by his reliance upon older ideas of political economy linked to a pre-Hobbesian tradition of Natural Law influenced by Biblical literature, by the Elizabethan, Richard Hooker, by various medieval writers and by the classics of ancient Greece and Rome, particularly the works of Plato and Xenophon. Intimations of his organic social views may be found in his early children's tale, The King of the Golden River (1841), which found mature expression in the 1878 Constitution he wrote for The Guild of St. George, his late social experiment. After 1854, his ideas on political economy were steadily informed by works and commentaries dealing with practical environmental issues concerning architecture and common lands conservation, public health, transportation, science policy and pollution.
doi_str_mv 10.3197/096734012X13225062753705
format Article
fullrecord <record><control><sourceid>jstor_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_1272069663</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><ingid>whp/eh/2012/00000018/00000001/art00007</ingid><jstor_id>23250895</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>23250895</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c527t-8111a8b6f4af7a90d71ab26fa4a2678860c286ae44ef708c5e2a6c68f04632d23</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqNkUFvFCEYhonRxHX1J5hw08tY-JgBxoPGNLWa1NjUmngjdAa6rLMwArOm_nqZnY2eauTCR76HB3hBCFPyitFWnJCWC1YTCt8oA2gIB9EwQZoHaEVFA5UgwB6i1YxVhROP0ZOUtoQAByArdHm9MfgyDC67LuFgcS7r8zD0xuMrtzfxNb6a0nfncfD4zO9dDH5nfMba9wf2S9bZBa_j3aE0T9Ejq4dknh3nNfr6_uz69EN18fn84-m7i6prQORKUkq1vOG21lbolvSC6hvgVtcauJCSkw4k16aujRVEdo0BzTsuLak5gx7YGr1YvGMMPyaTstq51Jlh0N6EKamWM86Y5LKQL_9JUhBAeMsLvkZyQbsYUorGqjG6XXmbokTNcav74i5b3y5bhzm1MYRhjCYltQ1T9CWI_zE8XwzblEP8czKwAsl27r9Z-s7flh_Qf9U_N6MyGwVFqshhUHksCFU65rkQRfDpHoHrDo7j1YTaU-lp8QElEpiiNW1Ub6yehqyyjur2l0qC_QaJtrtQ</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1272069663</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State</title><source>Jstor Complete Legacy</source><creator>MacDonald, Graham A.</creator><creatorcontrib>MacDonald, Graham A.</creatorcontrib><description>In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology, hostile to mass machine production. Mumford was not the first to draw attention to the relevance of Ruskin for developing environmental and urban planning theories. Despite Ruskin's frequent castigation of John Stuart Mill's ideas on political economy, and others of the eighteenth century 'classical school' of political economy, he shared a good deal with them. With Mill he displayed a preference for governments empowered to exercise legislative control in the imposition of limits to growth and in safeguarding worker interests. Notions of the 'stationary state' can be found in the mature writings of Malthus, Mill and Ruskin. In Ruskin's case, however, his views were shaped by his reliance upon older ideas of political economy linked to a pre-Hobbesian tradition of Natural Law influenced by Biblical literature, by the Elizabethan, Richard Hooker, by various medieval writers and by the classics of ancient Greece and Rome, particularly the works of Plato and Xenophon. Intimations of his organic social views may be found in his early children's tale, The King of the Golden River (1841), which found mature expression in the 1878 Constitution he wrote for The Guild of St. George, his late social experiment. After 1854, his ideas on political economy were steadily informed by works and commentaries dealing with practical environmental issues concerning architecture and common lands conservation, public health, transportation, science policy and pollution.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0967-3407</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1752-7023</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.3197/096734012X13225062753705</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Isle of Harris, UK: The White Horse Press</publisher><subject>Classical economics ; Consumption ; Economic thought ; Environmental conservation ; Environmental history ; Environmental politics ; Geology ; Green economics ; Land Use ; Nature conservation ; Political economy ; Pollution ; Public health ; Public policy ; Ruskin ; Ruskin, John ; Scientific research ; State intervention ; Stationary State ; United Kingdom ; Urban economics ; Utopian fiction ; Valleys ; Victorians</subject><ispartof>Environment and history, 2012-02, Vol.18 (1), p.125-150</ispartof><rights>2012 The White Horse Press</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c527t-8111a8b6f4af7a90d71ab26fa4a2678860c286ae44ef708c5e2a6c68f04632d23</citedby></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/23250895$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/23250895$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,776,780,799,27901,27902,57992,58225</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>MacDonald, Graham A.</creatorcontrib><title>The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State</title><title>Environment and history</title><description>In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology, hostile to mass machine production. Mumford was not the first to draw attention to the relevance of Ruskin for developing environmental and urban planning theories. Despite Ruskin's frequent castigation of John Stuart Mill's ideas on political economy, and others of the eighteenth century 'classical school' of political economy, he shared a good deal with them. With Mill he displayed a preference for governments empowered to exercise legislative control in the imposition of limits to growth and in safeguarding worker interests. Notions of the 'stationary state' can be found in the mature writings of Malthus, Mill and Ruskin. In Ruskin's case, however, his views were shaped by his reliance upon older ideas of political economy linked to a pre-Hobbesian tradition of Natural Law influenced by Biblical literature, by the Elizabethan, Richard Hooker, by various medieval writers and by the classics of ancient Greece and Rome, particularly the works of Plato and Xenophon. Intimations of his organic social views may be found in his early children's tale, The King of the Golden River (1841), which found mature expression in the 1878 Constitution he wrote for The Guild of St. George, his late social experiment. After 1854, his ideas on political economy were steadily informed by works and commentaries dealing with practical environmental issues concerning architecture and common lands conservation, public health, transportation, science policy and pollution.</description><subject>Classical economics</subject><subject>Consumption</subject><subject>Economic thought</subject><subject>Environmental conservation</subject><subject>Environmental history</subject><subject>Environmental politics</subject><subject>Geology</subject><subject>Green economics</subject><subject>Land Use</subject><subject>Nature conservation</subject><subject>Political economy</subject><subject>Pollution</subject><subject>Public health</subject><subject>Public policy</subject><subject>Ruskin</subject><subject>Ruskin, John</subject><subject>Scientific research</subject><subject>State intervention</subject><subject>Stationary State</subject><subject>United Kingdom</subject><subject>Urban economics</subject><subject>Utopian fiction</subject><subject>Valleys</subject><subject>Victorians</subject><issn>0967-3407</issn><issn>1752-7023</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2012</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><recordid>eNqNkUFvFCEYhonRxHX1J5hw08tY-JgBxoPGNLWa1NjUmngjdAa6rLMwArOm_nqZnY2eauTCR76HB3hBCFPyitFWnJCWC1YTCt8oA2gIB9EwQZoHaEVFA5UgwB6i1YxVhROP0ZOUtoQAByArdHm9MfgyDC67LuFgcS7r8zD0xuMrtzfxNb6a0nfncfD4zO9dDH5nfMba9wf2S9bZBa_j3aE0T9Ejq4dknh3nNfr6_uz69EN18fn84-m7i6prQORKUkq1vOG21lbolvSC6hvgVtcauJCSkw4k16aujRVEdo0BzTsuLak5gx7YGr1YvGMMPyaTstq51Jlh0N6EKamWM86Y5LKQL_9JUhBAeMsLvkZyQbsYUorGqjG6XXmbokTNcav74i5b3y5bhzm1MYRhjCYltQ1T9CWI_zE8XwzblEP8czKwAsl27r9Z-s7flh_Qf9U_N6MyGwVFqshhUHksCFU65rkQRfDpHoHrDo7j1YTaU-lp8QElEpiiNW1Ub6yehqyyjur2l0qC_QaJtrtQ</recordid><startdate>20120201</startdate><enddate>20120201</enddate><creator>MacDonald, Graham A.</creator><general>The White Horse Press</general><general>White Horse Press</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>C18</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope></search><sort><creationdate>20120201</creationdate><title>The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State</title><author>MacDonald, Graham A.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c527t-8111a8b6f4af7a90d71ab26fa4a2678860c286ae44ef708c5e2a6c68f04632d23</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2012</creationdate><topic>Classical economics</topic><topic>Consumption</topic><topic>Economic thought</topic><topic>Environmental conservation</topic><topic>Environmental history</topic><topic>Environmental politics</topic><topic>Geology</topic><topic>Green economics</topic><topic>Land Use</topic><topic>Nature conservation</topic><topic>Political economy</topic><topic>Pollution</topic><topic>Public health</topic><topic>Public policy</topic><topic>Ruskin</topic><topic>Ruskin, John</topic><topic>Scientific research</topic><topic>State intervention</topic><topic>Stationary State</topic><topic>United Kingdom</topic><topic>Urban economics</topic><topic>Utopian fiction</topic><topic>Valleys</topic><topic>Victorians</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>MacDonald, Graham A.</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Humanities Index</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><jtitle>Environment and history</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>MacDonald, Graham A.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State</atitle><jtitle>Environment and history</jtitle><date>2012-02-01</date><risdate>2012</risdate><volume>18</volume><issue>1</issue><spage>125</spage><epage>150</epage><pages>125-150</pages><issn>0967-3407</issn><eissn>1752-7023</eissn><abstract>In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology, hostile to mass machine production. Mumford was not the first to draw attention to the relevance of Ruskin for developing environmental and urban planning theories. Despite Ruskin's frequent castigation of John Stuart Mill's ideas on political economy, and others of the eighteenth century 'classical school' of political economy, he shared a good deal with them. With Mill he displayed a preference for governments empowered to exercise legislative control in the imposition of limits to growth and in safeguarding worker interests. Notions of the 'stationary state' can be found in the mature writings of Malthus, Mill and Ruskin. In Ruskin's case, however, his views were shaped by his reliance upon older ideas of political economy linked to a pre-Hobbesian tradition of Natural Law influenced by Biblical literature, by the Elizabethan, Richard Hooker, by various medieval writers and by the classics of ancient Greece and Rome, particularly the works of Plato and Xenophon. Intimations of his organic social views may be found in his early children's tale, The King of the Golden River (1841), which found mature expression in the 1878 Constitution he wrote for The Guild of St. George, his late social experiment. After 1854, his ideas on political economy were steadily informed by works and commentaries dealing with practical environmental issues concerning architecture and common lands conservation, public health, transportation, science policy and pollution.</abstract><cop>Isle of Harris, UK</cop><pub>The White Horse Press</pub><doi>10.3197/096734012X13225062753705</doi><tpages>26</tpages></addata></record>
fulltext fulltext
identifier ISSN: 0967-3407
ispartof Environment and history, 2012-02, Vol.18 (1), p.125-150
issn 0967-3407
1752-7023
language eng
recordid cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_1272069663
source Jstor Complete Legacy
subjects Classical economics
Consumption
Economic thought
Environmental conservation
Environmental history
Environmental politics
Geology
Green economics
Land Use
Nature conservation
Political economy
Pollution
Public health
Public policy
Ruskin
Ruskin, John
Scientific research
State intervention
Stationary State
United Kingdom
Urban economics
Utopian fiction
Valleys
Victorians
title The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State
url https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-02-10T15%3A07%3A20IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-jstor_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=The%20Politics%20of%20the%20Golden%20River:%20Ruskin%20on%20Environment%20and%20the%20Stationary%20State&rft.jtitle=Environment%20and%20history&rft.au=MacDonald,%20Graham%20A.&rft.date=2012-02-01&rft.volume=18&rft.issue=1&rft.spage=125&rft.epage=150&rft.pages=125-150&rft.issn=0967-3407&rft.eissn=1752-7023&rft_id=info:doi/10.3197/096734012X13225062753705&rft_dat=%3Cjstor_proqu%3E23250895%3C/jstor_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1272069663&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_ingid=whp/eh/2012/00000018/00000001/art00007&rft_jstor_id=23250895&rfr_iscdi=true