The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State
In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology,...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Environment and history 2012-02, Vol.18 (1), p.125-150 |
---|---|
1. Verfasser: | |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 150 |
---|---|
container_issue | 1 |
container_start_page | 125 |
container_title | Environment and history |
container_volume | 18 |
creator | MacDonald, Graham A. |
description | In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology,
hostile to mass machine production. Mumford was not the first to draw attention to the relevance of Ruskin for developing environmental and urban planning theories. Despite Ruskin's frequent castigation of John Stuart Mill's ideas on political economy, and others of the eighteenth century
'classical school' of political economy, he shared a good deal with them. With Mill he displayed a preference for governments empowered to exercise legislative control in the imposition of limits to growth and in safeguarding worker interests. Notions of the 'stationary state' can be found
in the mature writings of Malthus, Mill and Ruskin. In Ruskin's case, however, his views were shaped by his reliance upon older ideas of political economy linked to a pre-Hobbesian tradition of Natural Law influenced by Biblical literature, by the Elizabethan, Richard Hooker, by various medieval
writers and by the classics of ancient Greece and Rome, particularly the works of Plato and Xenophon. Intimations of his organic social views may be found in his early children's tale, The King of the Golden River (1841), which found mature expression in the 1878 Constitution he wrote
for The Guild of St. George, his late social experiment. After 1854, his ideas on political economy were steadily informed by works and commentaries dealing with practical environmental issues concerning architecture and common lands conservation, public health, transportation, science policy
and pollution. |
doi_str_mv | 10.3197/096734012X13225062753705 |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>jstor_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_1272069663</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><ingid>whp/eh/2012/00000018/00000001/art00007</ingid><jstor_id>23250895</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>23250895</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c527t-8111a8b6f4af7a90d71ab26fa4a2678860c286ae44ef708c5e2a6c68f04632d23</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqNkUFvFCEYhonRxHX1J5hw08tY-JgBxoPGNLWa1NjUmngjdAa6rLMwArOm_nqZnY2eauTCR76HB3hBCFPyitFWnJCWC1YTCt8oA2gIB9EwQZoHaEVFA5UgwB6i1YxVhROP0ZOUtoQAByArdHm9MfgyDC67LuFgcS7r8zD0xuMrtzfxNb6a0nfncfD4zO9dDH5nfMba9wf2S9bZBa_j3aE0T9Ejq4dknh3nNfr6_uz69EN18fn84-m7i6prQORKUkq1vOG21lbolvSC6hvgVtcauJCSkw4k16aujRVEdo0BzTsuLak5gx7YGr1YvGMMPyaTstq51Jlh0N6EKamWM86Y5LKQL_9JUhBAeMsLvkZyQbsYUorGqjG6XXmbokTNcav74i5b3y5bhzm1MYRhjCYltQ1T9CWI_zE8XwzblEP8czKwAsl27r9Z-s7flh_Qf9U_N6MyGwVFqshhUHksCFU65rkQRfDpHoHrDo7j1YTaU-lp8QElEpiiNW1Ub6yehqyyjur2l0qC_QaJtrtQ</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1272069663</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State</title><source>Jstor Complete Legacy</source><creator>MacDonald, Graham A.</creator><creatorcontrib>MacDonald, Graham A.</creatorcontrib><description>In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology,
hostile to mass machine production. Mumford was not the first to draw attention to the relevance of Ruskin for developing environmental and urban planning theories. Despite Ruskin's frequent castigation of John Stuart Mill's ideas on political economy, and others of the eighteenth century
'classical school' of political economy, he shared a good deal with them. With Mill he displayed a preference for governments empowered to exercise legislative control in the imposition of limits to growth and in safeguarding worker interests. Notions of the 'stationary state' can be found
in the mature writings of Malthus, Mill and Ruskin. In Ruskin's case, however, his views were shaped by his reliance upon older ideas of political economy linked to a pre-Hobbesian tradition of Natural Law influenced by Biblical literature, by the Elizabethan, Richard Hooker, by various medieval
writers and by the classics of ancient Greece and Rome, particularly the works of Plato and Xenophon. Intimations of his organic social views may be found in his early children's tale, The King of the Golden River (1841), which found mature expression in the 1878 Constitution he wrote
for The Guild of St. George, his late social experiment. After 1854, his ideas on political economy were steadily informed by works and commentaries dealing with practical environmental issues concerning architecture and common lands conservation, public health, transportation, science policy
and pollution.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0967-3407</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1752-7023</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.3197/096734012X13225062753705</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Isle of Harris, UK: The White Horse Press</publisher><subject>Classical economics ; Consumption ; Economic thought ; Environmental conservation ; Environmental history ; Environmental politics ; Geology ; Green economics ; Land Use ; Nature conservation ; Political economy ; Pollution ; Public health ; Public policy ; Ruskin ; Ruskin, John ; Scientific research ; State intervention ; Stationary State ; United Kingdom ; Urban economics ; Utopian fiction ; Valleys ; Victorians</subject><ispartof>Environment and history, 2012-02, Vol.18 (1), p.125-150</ispartof><rights>2012 The White Horse Press</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c527t-8111a8b6f4af7a90d71ab26fa4a2678860c286ae44ef708c5e2a6c68f04632d23</citedby></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/23250895$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/23250895$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,776,780,799,27901,27902,57992,58225</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>MacDonald, Graham A.</creatorcontrib><title>The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State</title><title>Environment and history</title><description>In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology,
hostile to mass machine production. Mumford was not the first to draw attention to the relevance of Ruskin for developing environmental and urban planning theories. Despite Ruskin's frequent castigation of John Stuart Mill's ideas on political economy, and others of the eighteenth century
'classical school' of political economy, he shared a good deal with them. With Mill he displayed a preference for governments empowered to exercise legislative control in the imposition of limits to growth and in safeguarding worker interests. Notions of the 'stationary state' can be found
in the mature writings of Malthus, Mill and Ruskin. In Ruskin's case, however, his views were shaped by his reliance upon older ideas of political economy linked to a pre-Hobbesian tradition of Natural Law influenced by Biblical literature, by the Elizabethan, Richard Hooker, by various medieval
writers and by the classics of ancient Greece and Rome, particularly the works of Plato and Xenophon. Intimations of his organic social views may be found in his early children's tale, The King of the Golden River (1841), which found mature expression in the 1878 Constitution he wrote
for The Guild of St. George, his late social experiment. After 1854, his ideas on political economy were steadily informed by works and commentaries dealing with practical environmental issues concerning architecture and common lands conservation, public health, transportation, science policy
and pollution.</description><subject>Classical economics</subject><subject>Consumption</subject><subject>Economic thought</subject><subject>Environmental conservation</subject><subject>Environmental history</subject><subject>Environmental politics</subject><subject>Geology</subject><subject>Green economics</subject><subject>Land Use</subject><subject>Nature conservation</subject><subject>Political economy</subject><subject>Pollution</subject><subject>Public health</subject><subject>Public policy</subject><subject>Ruskin</subject><subject>Ruskin, John</subject><subject>Scientific research</subject><subject>State intervention</subject><subject>Stationary State</subject><subject>United Kingdom</subject><subject>Urban economics</subject><subject>Utopian fiction</subject><subject>Valleys</subject><subject>Victorians</subject><issn>0967-3407</issn><issn>1752-7023</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2012</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><recordid>eNqNkUFvFCEYhonRxHX1J5hw08tY-JgBxoPGNLWa1NjUmngjdAa6rLMwArOm_nqZnY2eauTCR76HB3hBCFPyitFWnJCWC1YTCt8oA2gIB9EwQZoHaEVFA5UgwB6i1YxVhROP0ZOUtoQAByArdHm9MfgyDC67LuFgcS7r8zD0xuMrtzfxNb6a0nfncfD4zO9dDH5nfMba9wf2S9bZBa_j3aE0T9Ejq4dknh3nNfr6_uz69EN18fn84-m7i6prQORKUkq1vOG21lbolvSC6hvgVtcauJCSkw4k16aujRVEdo0BzTsuLak5gx7YGr1YvGMMPyaTstq51Jlh0N6EKamWM86Y5LKQL_9JUhBAeMsLvkZyQbsYUorGqjG6XXmbokTNcav74i5b3y5bhzm1MYRhjCYltQ1T9CWI_zE8XwzblEP8czKwAsl27r9Z-s7flh_Qf9U_N6MyGwVFqshhUHksCFU65rkQRfDpHoHrDo7j1YTaU-lp8QElEpiiNW1Ub6yehqyyjur2l0qC_QaJtrtQ</recordid><startdate>20120201</startdate><enddate>20120201</enddate><creator>MacDonald, Graham A.</creator><general>The White Horse Press</general><general>White Horse Press</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>C18</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope></search><sort><creationdate>20120201</creationdate><title>The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State</title><author>MacDonald, Graham A.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c527t-8111a8b6f4af7a90d71ab26fa4a2678860c286ae44ef708c5e2a6c68f04632d23</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2012</creationdate><topic>Classical economics</topic><topic>Consumption</topic><topic>Economic thought</topic><topic>Environmental conservation</topic><topic>Environmental history</topic><topic>Environmental politics</topic><topic>Geology</topic><topic>Green economics</topic><topic>Land Use</topic><topic>Nature conservation</topic><topic>Political economy</topic><topic>Pollution</topic><topic>Public health</topic><topic>Public policy</topic><topic>Ruskin</topic><topic>Ruskin, John</topic><topic>Scientific research</topic><topic>State intervention</topic><topic>Stationary State</topic><topic>United Kingdom</topic><topic>Urban economics</topic><topic>Utopian fiction</topic><topic>Valleys</topic><topic>Victorians</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>MacDonald, Graham A.</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Humanities Index</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><jtitle>Environment and history</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>MacDonald, Graham A.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State</atitle><jtitle>Environment and history</jtitle><date>2012-02-01</date><risdate>2012</risdate><volume>18</volume><issue>1</issue><spage>125</spage><epage>150</epage><pages>125-150</pages><issn>0967-3407</issn><eissn>1752-7023</eissn><abstract>In 1938 Lewis Mumford stated that 'Ruskin was the first economist to express the realities of energy income and living standards in relation to production'. Ruskin's ideas on wise economic distribution and consumption were developed from within an older and broader view of technology,
hostile to mass machine production. Mumford was not the first to draw attention to the relevance of Ruskin for developing environmental and urban planning theories. Despite Ruskin's frequent castigation of John Stuart Mill's ideas on political economy, and others of the eighteenth century
'classical school' of political economy, he shared a good deal with them. With Mill he displayed a preference for governments empowered to exercise legislative control in the imposition of limits to growth and in safeguarding worker interests. Notions of the 'stationary state' can be found
in the mature writings of Malthus, Mill and Ruskin. In Ruskin's case, however, his views were shaped by his reliance upon older ideas of political economy linked to a pre-Hobbesian tradition of Natural Law influenced by Biblical literature, by the Elizabethan, Richard Hooker, by various medieval
writers and by the classics of ancient Greece and Rome, particularly the works of Plato and Xenophon. Intimations of his organic social views may be found in his early children's tale, The King of the Golden River (1841), which found mature expression in the 1878 Constitution he wrote
for The Guild of St. George, his late social experiment. After 1854, his ideas on political economy were steadily informed by works and commentaries dealing with practical environmental issues concerning architecture and common lands conservation, public health, transportation, science policy
and pollution.</abstract><cop>Isle of Harris, UK</cop><pub>The White Horse Press</pub><doi>10.3197/096734012X13225062753705</doi><tpages>26</tpages></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0967-3407 |
ispartof | Environment and history, 2012-02, Vol.18 (1), p.125-150 |
issn | 0967-3407 1752-7023 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_miscellaneous_1272069663 |
source | Jstor Complete Legacy |
subjects | Classical economics Consumption Economic thought Environmental conservation Environmental history Environmental politics Geology Green economics Land Use Nature conservation Political economy Pollution Public health Public policy Ruskin Ruskin, John Scientific research State intervention Stationary State United Kingdom Urban economics Utopian fiction Valleys Victorians |
title | The Politics of the Golden River: Ruskin on Environment and the Stationary State |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-02-10T15%3A07%3A20IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-jstor_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=The%20Politics%20of%20the%20Golden%20River:%20Ruskin%20on%20Environment%20and%20the%20Stationary%20State&rft.jtitle=Environment%20and%20history&rft.au=MacDonald,%20Graham%20A.&rft.date=2012-02-01&rft.volume=18&rft.issue=1&rft.spage=125&rft.epage=150&rft.pages=125-150&rft.issn=0967-3407&rft.eissn=1752-7023&rft_id=info:doi/10.3197/096734012X13225062753705&rft_dat=%3Cjstor_proqu%3E23250895%3C/jstor_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1272069663&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_ingid=whp/eh/2012/00000018/00000001/art00007&rft_jstor_id=23250895&rfr_iscdi=true |