Alternatives to expropriation: rent, credit and peasant landholding in medieval Europe and modern Palestine

[...]this was neither a universal process nor one that was dependent upon unique sets of prevailing conditions; instead, the persistence of, or introduction of, new institutional and economic structures and practices (such as seigneurial expectations, communal or familial convention, governmental le...

Ausführliche Beschreibung

Gespeichert in:
Bibliographische Detailangaben
Veröffentlicht in:Continuity and change 2021-08, Vol.36 (2), p.141-148
1. Verfasser: Schofield, Phillipp R.
Format: Artikel
Sprache:eng
Schlagworte:
Online-Zugang:Volltext
Tags: Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
container_end_page 148
container_issue 2
container_start_page 141
container_title Continuity and change
container_volume 36
creator Schofield, Phillipp R.
description [...]this was neither a universal process nor one that was dependent upon unique sets of prevailing conditions; instead, the persistence of, or introduction of, new institutional and economic structures and practices (such as seigneurial expectations, communal or familial convention, governmental legislation, the relative fluidity of capital, and the exercise of local norms of dealing) may all have combined, jointly or severally, to affect the degree to which land was retained by a diminished tenantry or wholly appropriated. While expropriation is not a term confined to Marxist dialectic it has, since Marx wrote Capital and discussed the expropriation of the agricultural population from the land, been closely associated with the English later middle ages and the period of transition from feudalism to capitalism.2 The essential components for expropriation were the diminution of a pre-existing mode of production, namely feudalism, and an effective abandonment of a peasant tenantry to a new mode of production, capitalism, founded on new economic principles, including greater specialisation and market production. [...]the confiscation and legal sale of the debtor's goods in order to pay the creditor and settle the debt gave rise to a wide circulation of effects and properties in two circuits: a very dynamic second-hand market, only recently attracting the attention of historians and important for historical awareness of material culture and consumption patterns, and an equally very active peasant land market, both of plots and holdings, which has been a significant research focus for historians for a number of years.8 The way in which the land was seized and sold judicially, the role of brokers and judicial agents, the sale prices in relation to market prices, buyers, and so on are all potentially relevant in this respect. Before there is capitalism, according to Brenner, there can be no process of proletarianization for the reason that, under feudalism, much of the economy is protected by institutions and a non-market foundation to the economy which rejects processes that will defeat the essential function of that pre-capitalist economy, namely for peasants to hold on to land as ‘the foundation for their economic reproduction’.9 Brenner describes a ‘safety first’ approach on the part of peasants which suggests that morcellisation or parcellisation was more likely to occur than was accumulation or agglomeration under feudalism; the lack of sufficient marketin
doi_str_mv 10.1017/S0268416021000199
format Article
fullrecord <record><control><sourceid>proquest_cross</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_journals_2583929094</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><cupid>10_1017_S0268416021000199</cupid><sourcerecordid>2583929094</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c2759-4b2af551cea2cebec90bde6a2caf43202a2f532eba49d0874576eb85d89b52043</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNp1kNFLwzAQxoMoOKd_gG8BX60madMmvo2xqTBQUMG3kjTX2dkmM-mG_vembuCD-HTc3e_7ju8QOqfkihJaXD8RlouM5oRRQgiV8gCNaJbLhFHxeohGwzoZ9sfoJIRVZATJ6Qi9T9oevFV9s4WAe4fhc-3d2jdx4uwN9mD7S1x5ME2PlTV4DSoo2-M2Nm-uNY1d4sbiLgKwVS2ebaIcftDOmWiNH1ULoW8snKKjWrUBzvZ1jF7ms-fpXbJ4uL2fThZJxQouk0wzVXNOK1CsAg2VJNpAHhtVZykjTLGapwy0yqQhosh4kYMW3AipOSNZOkYXO9-Y5GMTb5crt4kZ21AyLlLJJJEDRXdU5V0IHuoypu6U_yopKYefln9-GjXpXqM67RuzhF_r_1Xft256FA</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>2583929094</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Alternatives to expropriation: rent, credit and peasant landholding in medieval Europe and modern Palestine</title><source>Cambridge Journals</source><source>Sociological Abstracts</source><creator>Schofield, Phillipp R.</creator><creatorcontrib>Schofield, Phillipp R.</creatorcontrib><description>[...]this was neither a universal process nor one that was dependent upon unique sets of prevailing conditions; instead, the persistence of, or introduction of, new institutional and economic structures and practices (such as seigneurial expectations, communal or familial convention, governmental legislation, the relative fluidity of capital, and the exercise of local norms of dealing) may all have combined, jointly or severally, to affect the degree to which land was retained by a diminished tenantry or wholly appropriated. While expropriation is not a term confined to Marxist dialectic it has, since Marx wrote Capital and discussed the expropriation of the agricultural population from the land, been closely associated with the English later middle ages and the period of transition from feudalism to capitalism.2 The essential components for expropriation were the diminution of a pre-existing mode of production, namely feudalism, and an effective abandonment of a peasant tenantry to a new mode of production, capitalism, founded on new economic principles, including greater specialisation and market production. [...]the confiscation and legal sale of the debtor's goods in order to pay the creditor and settle the debt gave rise to a wide circulation of effects and properties in two circuits: a very dynamic second-hand market, only recently attracting the attention of historians and important for historical awareness of material culture and consumption patterns, and an equally very active peasant land market, both of plots and holdings, which has been a significant research focus for historians for a number of years.8 The way in which the land was seized and sold judicially, the role of brokers and judicial agents, the sale prices in relation to market prices, buyers, and so on are all potentially relevant in this respect. Before there is capitalism, according to Brenner, there can be no process of proletarianization for the reason that, under feudalism, much of the economy is protected by institutions and a non-market foundation to the economy which rejects processes that will defeat the essential function of that pre-capitalist economy, namely for peasants to hold on to land as ‘the foundation for their economic reproduction’.9 Brenner describes a ‘safety first’ approach on the part of peasants which suggests that morcellisation or parcellisation was more likely to occur than was accumulation or agglomeration under feudalism; the lack of sufficient marketing structures discouraged distance from landholding and the means of production or, as he also presents it, the peasant's means of subsistence.10 To follow Brenner, then, as well as those such as E.A. Kosminsky who preceded him, is to accept that expropriation will not occur under feudalism but will occur with some rapidity ‘in the presence of the market’.11 As the articles presented here make clear, however, conditions that speak to a market presence and elements of a nascent capitalism do not necessarily prompt a process of expropriation; instead, even allowing for the inequalities of the market and the relative disadvantage of peasant tenants in their dealings with wealthier merchants, creditors and landholders, the studies gathered here show how poorer peasants, the debtors and the under-capitalised parties in such arrangements, managed to, or were given licence to, hold on to their land.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0268-4160</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1469-218X</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1017/S0268416021000199</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press</publisher><subject>Accumulation ; Agricultural production ; Capitalism ; Circuits ; Confiscation ; Creditors ; Debt ; Expropriation ; Feudalism ; Historians ; Inequality ; Land ; Land market ; Legislation ; Marketing ; Markets ; Marxism ; Material culture ; Merchants ; Middle Ages ; Modes of production ; Peasants ; Prices ; Proletarianization ; Property rights ; Tenants</subject><ispartof>Continuity and change, 2021-08, Vol.36 (2), p.141-148</ispartof><rights>Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2021</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><oa>free_for_read</oa><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c2759-4b2af551cea2cebec90bde6a2caf43202a2f532eba49d0874576eb85d89b52043</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c2759-4b2af551cea2cebec90bde6a2caf43202a2f532eba49d0874576eb85d89b52043</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.cambridge.org/core/product/identifier/S0268416021000199/type/journal_article$$EHTML$$P50$$Gcambridge$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>164,314,780,784,27344,27924,27925,33774,55628</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Schofield, Phillipp R.</creatorcontrib><title>Alternatives to expropriation: rent, credit and peasant landholding in medieval Europe and modern Palestine</title><title>Continuity and change</title><addtitle>Cont. Change</addtitle><description>[...]this was neither a universal process nor one that was dependent upon unique sets of prevailing conditions; instead, the persistence of, or introduction of, new institutional and economic structures and practices (such as seigneurial expectations, communal or familial convention, governmental legislation, the relative fluidity of capital, and the exercise of local norms of dealing) may all have combined, jointly or severally, to affect the degree to which land was retained by a diminished tenantry or wholly appropriated. While expropriation is not a term confined to Marxist dialectic it has, since Marx wrote Capital and discussed the expropriation of the agricultural population from the land, been closely associated with the English later middle ages and the period of transition from feudalism to capitalism.2 The essential components for expropriation were the diminution of a pre-existing mode of production, namely feudalism, and an effective abandonment of a peasant tenantry to a new mode of production, capitalism, founded on new economic principles, including greater specialisation and market production. [...]the confiscation and legal sale of the debtor's goods in order to pay the creditor and settle the debt gave rise to a wide circulation of effects and properties in two circuits: a very dynamic second-hand market, only recently attracting the attention of historians and important for historical awareness of material culture and consumption patterns, and an equally very active peasant land market, both of plots and holdings, which has been a significant research focus for historians for a number of years.8 The way in which the land was seized and sold judicially, the role of brokers and judicial agents, the sale prices in relation to market prices, buyers, and so on are all potentially relevant in this respect. Before there is capitalism, according to Brenner, there can be no process of proletarianization for the reason that, under feudalism, much of the economy is protected by institutions and a non-market foundation to the economy which rejects processes that will defeat the essential function of that pre-capitalist economy, namely for peasants to hold on to land as ‘the foundation for their economic reproduction’.9 Brenner describes a ‘safety first’ approach on the part of peasants which suggests that morcellisation or parcellisation was more likely to occur than was accumulation or agglomeration under feudalism; the lack of sufficient marketing structures discouraged distance from landholding and the means of production or, as he also presents it, the peasant's means of subsistence.10 To follow Brenner, then, as well as those such as E.A. Kosminsky who preceded him, is to accept that expropriation will not occur under feudalism but will occur with some rapidity ‘in the presence of the market’.11 As the articles presented here make clear, however, conditions that speak to a market presence and elements of a nascent capitalism do not necessarily prompt a process of expropriation; instead, even allowing for the inequalities of the market and the relative disadvantage of peasant tenants in their dealings with wealthier merchants, creditors and landholders, the studies gathered here show how poorer peasants, the debtors and the under-capitalised parties in such arrangements, managed to, or were given licence to, hold on to their land.</description><subject>Accumulation</subject><subject>Agricultural production</subject><subject>Capitalism</subject><subject>Circuits</subject><subject>Confiscation</subject><subject>Creditors</subject><subject>Debt</subject><subject>Expropriation</subject><subject>Feudalism</subject><subject>Historians</subject><subject>Inequality</subject><subject>Land</subject><subject>Land market</subject><subject>Legislation</subject><subject>Marketing</subject><subject>Markets</subject><subject>Marxism</subject><subject>Material culture</subject><subject>Merchants</subject><subject>Middle Ages</subject><subject>Modes of production</subject><subject>Peasants</subject><subject>Prices</subject><subject>Proletarianization</subject><subject>Property rights</subject><subject>Tenants</subject><issn>0268-4160</issn><issn>1469-218X</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2021</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>8G5</sourceid><sourceid>ABUWG</sourceid><sourceid>AFKRA</sourceid><sourceid>AIMQZ</sourceid><sourceid>AVQMV</sourceid><sourceid>AZQEC</sourceid><sourceid>BENPR</sourceid><sourceid>BHHNA</sourceid><sourceid>CCPQU</sourceid><sourceid>DWQXO</sourceid><sourceid>GNUQQ</sourceid><sourceid>GUQSH</sourceid><sourceid>K50</sourceid><sourceid>M1D</sourceid><sourceid>M2O</sourceid><sourceid>PQHSC</sourceid><recordid>eNp1kNFLwzAQxoMoOKd_gG8BX60madMmvo2xqTBQUMG3kjTX2dkmM-mG_vembuCD-HTc3e_7ju8QOqfkihJaXD8RlouM5oRRQgiV8gCNaJbLhFHxeohGwzoZ9sfoJIRVZATJ6Qi9T9oevFV9s4WAe4fhc-3d2jdx4uwN9mD7S1x5ME2PlTV4DSoo2-M2Nm-uNY1d4sbiLgKwVS2ebaIcftDOmWiNH1ULoW8snKKjWrUBzvZ1jF7ms-fpXbJ4uL2fThZJxQouk0wzVXNOK1CsAg2VJNpAHhtVZykjTLGapwy0yqQhosh4kYMW3AipOSNZOkYXO9-Y5GMTb5crt4kZ21AyLlLJJJEDRXdU5V0IHuoypu6U_yopKYefln9-GjXpXqM67RuzhF_r_1Xft256FA</recordid><startdate>202108</startdate><enddate>202108</enddate><creator>Schofield, Phillipp R.</creator><general>Cambridge University Press</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>0-V</scope><scope>3V.</scope><scope>7U4</scope><scope>7XB</scope><scope>88J</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>8FK</scope><scope>8G5</scope><scope>ABUWG</scope><scope>AFKRA</scope><scope>AIMQZ</scope><scope>ALSLI</scope><scope>AVQMV</scope><scope>AZQEC</scope><scope>BENPR</scope><scope>BHHNA</scope><scope>C18</scope><scope>CCPQU</scope><scope>DWI</scope><scope>DWQXO</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>GNUQQ</scope><scope>GUQSH</scope><scope>HEHIP</scope><scope>JBE</scope><scope>K50</scope><scope>LIQON</scope><scope>M1D</scope><scope>M2O</scope><scope>M2R</scope><scope>M2S</scope><scope>MBDVC</scope><scope>PQEST</scope><scope>PQHSC</scope><scope>PQQKQ</scope><scope>PQUKI</scope><scope>PRINS</scope><scope>Q9U</scope><scope>S0X</scope><scope>WZK</scope></search><sort><creationdate>202108</creationdate><title>Alternatives to expropriation: rent, credit and peasant landholding in medieval Europe and modern Palestine</title><author>Schofield, Phillipp R.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c2759-4b2af551cea2cebec90bde6a2caf43202a2f532eba49d0874576eb85d89b52043</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2021</creationdate><topic>Accumulation</topic><topic>Agricultural production</topic><topic>Capitalism</topic><topic>Circuits</topic><topic>Confiscation</topic><topic>Creditors</topic><topic>Debt</topic><topic>Expropriation</topic><topic>Feudalism</topic><topic>Historians</topic><topic>Inequality</topic><topic>Land</topic><topic>Land market</topic><topic>Legislation</topic><topic>Marketing</topic><topic>Markets</topic><topic>Marxism</topic><topic>Material culture</topic><topic>Merchants</topic><topic>Middle Ages</topic><topic>Modes of production</topic><topic>Peasants</topic><topic>Prices</topic><topic>Proletarianization</topic><topic>Property rights</topic><topic>Tenants</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Schofield, Phillipp R.</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>ProQuest Social Sciences Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Corporate)</collection><collection>Sociological Abstracts (pre-2017)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>Social Science Database (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni) (purchase pre-March 2016)</collection><collection>Research Library (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central (Alumni Edition)</collection><collection>ProQuest Central UK/Ireland</collection><collection>ProQuest One Literature</collection><collection>Social Science Premium Collection</collection><collection>Arts Premium Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Essentials</collection><collection>ProQuest Central</collection><collection>Sociological Abstracts</collection><collection>Humanities Index</collection><collection>ProQuest One Community College</collection><collection>Sociological Abstracts</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Korea</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Student</collection><collection>Research Library Prep</collection><collection>Sociology Collection</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>Art, Design &amp; Architecture Collection</collection><collection>ProQuest One Literature - U.S. Customers Only</collection><collection>Arts &amp; Humanities Database</collection><collection>Research Library</collection><collection>Social Science Database</collection><collection>Sociology Database</collection><collection>Research Library (Corporate)</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic Eastern Edition (DO NOT USE)</collection><collection>History Study Center</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic</collection><collection>ProQuest One Academic UKI Edition</collection><collection>ProQuest Central China</collection><collection>ProQuest Central Basic</collection><collection>SIRS Editorial</collection><collection>Sociological Abstracts (Ovid)</collection><jtitle>Continuity and change</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Schofield, Phillipp R.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Alternatives to expropriation: rent, credit and peasant landholding in medieval Europe and modern Palestine</atitle><jtitle>Continuity and change</jtitle><addtitle>Cont. Change</addtitle><date>2021-08</date><risdate>2021</risdate><volume>36</volume><issue>2</issue><spage>141</spage><epage>148</epage><pages>141-148</pages><issn>0268-4160</issn><eissn>1469-218X</eissn><abstract>[...]this was neither a universal process nor one that was dependent upon unique sets of prevailing conditions; instead, the persistence of, or introduction of, new institutional and economic structures and practices (such as seigneurial expectations, communal or familial convention, governmental legislation, the relative fluidity of capital, and the exercise of local norms of dealing) may all have combined, jointly or severally, to affect the degree to which land was retained by a diminished tenantry or wholly appropriated. While expropriation is not a term confined to Marxist dialectic it has, since Marx wrote Capital and discussed the expropriation of the agricultural population from the land, been closely associated with the English later middle ages and the period of transition from feudalism to capitalism.2 The essential components for expropriation were the diminution of a pre-existing mode of production, namely feudalism, and an effective abandonment of a peasant tenantry to a new mode of production, capitalism, founded on new economic principles, including greater specialisation and market production. [...]the confiscation and legal sale of the debtor's goods in order to pay the creditor and settle the debt gave rise to a wide circulation of effects and properties in two circuits: a very dynamic second-hand market, only recently attracting the attention of historians and important for historical awareness of material culture and consumption patterns, and an equally very active peasant land market, both of plots and holdings, which has been a significant research focus for historians for a number of years.8 The way in which the land was seized and sold judicially, the role of brokers and judicial agents, the sale prices in relation to market prices, buyers, and so on are all potentially relevant in this respect. Before there is capitalism, according to Brenner, there can be no process of proletarianization for the reason that, under feudalism, much of the economy is protected by institutions and a non-market foundation to the economy which rejects processes that will defeat the essential function of that pre-capitalist economy, namely for peasants to hold on to land as ‘the foundation for their economic reproduction’.9 Brenner describes a ‘safety first’ approach on the part of peasants which suggests that morcellisation or parcellisation was more likely to occur than was accumulation or agglomeration under feudalism; the lack of sufficient marketing structures discouraged distance from landholding and the means of production or, as he also presents it, the peasant's means of subsistence.10 To follow Brenner, then, as well as those such as E.A. Kosminsky who preceded him, is to accept that expropriation will not occur under feudalism but will occur with some rapidity ‘in the presence of the market’.11 As the articles presented here make clear, however, conditions that speak to a market presence and elements of a nascent capitalism do not necessarily prompt a process of expropriation; instead, even allowing for the inequalities of the market and the relative disadvantage of peasant tenants in their dealings with wealthier merchants, creditors and landholders, the studies gathered here show how poorer peasants, the debtors and the under-capitalised parties in such arrangements, managed to, or were given licence to, hold on to their land.</abstract><cop>Cambridge, UK</cop><pub>Cambridge University Press</pub><doi>10.1017/S0268416021000199</doi><tpages>8</tpages><oa>free_for_read</oa></addata></record>
fulltext fulltext
identifier ISSN: 0268-4160
ispartof Continuity and change, 2021-08, Vol.36 (2), p.141-148
issn 0268-4160
1469-218X
language eng
recordid cdi_proquest_journals_2583929094
source Cambridge Journals; Sociological Abstracts
subjects Accumulation
Agricultural production
Capitalism
Circuits
Confiscation
Creditors
Debt
Expropriation
Feudalism
Historians
Inequality
Land
Land market
Legislation
Marketing
Markets
Marxism
Material culture
Merchants
Middle Ages
Modes of production
Peasants
Prices
Proletarianization
Property rights
Tenants
title Alternatives to expropriation: rent, credit and peasant landholding in medieval Europe and modern Palestine
url https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-05T11%3A48%3A35IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-proquest_cross&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Alternatives%20to%20expropriation:%20rent,%20credit%20and%20peasant%20landholding%20in%20medieval%20Europe%20and%20modern%20Palestine&rft.jtitle=Continuity%20and%20change&rft.au=Schofield,%20Phillipp%20R.&rft.date=2021-08&rft.volume=36&rft.issue=2&rft.spage=141&rft.epage=148&rft.pages=141-148&rft.issn=0268-4160&rft.eissn=1469-218X&rft_id=info:doi/10.1017/S0268416021000199&rft_dat=%3Cproquest_cross%3E2583929094%3C/proquest_cross%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=2583929094&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_cupid=10_1017_S0268416021000199&rfr_iscdi=true