Currency boards: More than a quick fix?

Once a popular colonial monetary arrangement, currency boards fell into disuse as countries gained political independence. But recently, currency boards have made a remarkable come-back. This essay takes a critical look at their performance. Are currency boards really a panacea for achieving low inf...

Ausführliche Beschreibung

Gespeichert in:
Bibliographische Detailangaben
Veröffentlicht in:Economic policy 2000-10, Vol.15 (31), p.269-335
Hauptverfasser: Ghosh, Atish R., Gulde, Anne-Marie, Wolf, Holger C.
Format: Artikel
Sprache:eng
Schlagworte:
Online-Zugang:Volltext
Tags: Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
container_end_page 335
container_issue 31
container_start_page 269
container_title Economic policy
container_volume 15
creator Ghosh, Atish R.
Gulde, Anne-Marie
Wolf, Holger C.
description Once a popular colonial monetary arrangement, currency boards fell into disuse as countries gained political independence. But recently, currency boards have made a remarkable come-back. This essay takes a critical look at their performance. Are currency boards really a panacea for achieving low inflation and high growth? Or do they merely provide a 'quick fix' allowing authorities to neglect fundamental reforms and thus fail to yield lasting benefits? We have three major findings. First, the historical track record of currency boards is sterling, with few instances of speculative attacks and virtually no 'involuntary' exits. Countries that did exit from currency boards did so mainly for political, rather than economic reasons, and such exits were usually uneventful. Second, modern currency boards have often been instituted to gain credibility following a period of high or hyperinflation, and in this regard, have been remarkably successful. Countries with currency boards experienced lower inflation and higher (if more volatile) GDP growth compared to both floating regimes and simple pegs. The inflation difference reflects both a lower growth rate of money supply (a 'discipline effect'), and a faster growth of money demand (a 'credibility effect'). The GDP growth effect is significant, but may simply reflect a rebound from depressed levels. Third, case studies reveal the successful introduction of a currency board to be far from trivial, requiring lengthy legal and institutional changes, as well as a broad economic and social consensus for the implied commitment. Moreover, there are thorny issues, as yet untested, regarding possible exits from a currency board. Thus currency boards do not provide easy solutions. But if introduced in the right circumstances, with some built-in flexibility, they can be an important tool for gaining credibility and achieving macroeconomic stabilization.
doi_str_mv 10.1111/1468-0327.00063
format Article
fullrecord <record><control><sourceid>jstor_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_journals_195296217</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><jstor_id>1344698</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>1344698</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c387t-876a9f7c5139d2817122bcd1858e56ba14277182c982f2821007b7835f8352903</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNpFkNFLwzAQxoMoWKfPvvhQfPGpWy5pk9QXkapT2CaIom8hTVNsp-uWtLD996ZW5sFxcN_vvuMOoXPAY_AxgZiJCFPCxxhjRg9QsO8cogATxqKYJeIYnThX9wjENEBXWWetWeldmDfKFu46nDfWhO2nWoUq3HSVXoZltb05RUel-nLm7K-O0NvD_Wv2GM2ep0_Z7SzSVPA2EpyptOQ6AZoWRAAHQnJdgEiESViuICacgyA6FaQkggDGPOeCJqVPkmI6QpeD79o2m864VtZNZ1d-pYTUE4wA99BkgLRtnLOmlGtbfSu7k4Bl_wzZny770-XvM_zExTBRu7ax_ziNY5YKL0eDXLnWbPeyskvJOOWJfF9MJXzczV8WDLzvD2ujZVA</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>195296217</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Currency boards: More than a quick fix?</title><source>PAIS Index</source><source>EBSCOhost Business Source Complete</source><source>JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing</source><source>Oxford University Press Journals All Titles (1996-Current)</source><creator>Ghosh, Atish R. ; Gulde, Anne-Marie ; Wolf, Holger C.</creator><creatorcontrib>Ghosh, Atish R. ; Gulde, Anne-Marie ; Wolf, Holger C.</creatorcontrib><description>Once a popular colonial monetary arrangement, currency boards fell into disuse as countries gained political independence. But recently, currency boards have made a remarkable come-back. This essay takes a critical look at their performance. Are currency boards really a panacea for achieving low inflation and high growth? Or do they merely provide a 'quick fix' allowing authorities to neglect fundamental reforms and thus fail to yield lasting benefits? We have three major findings. First, the historical track record of currency boards is sterling, with few instances of speculative attacks and virtually no 'involuntary' exits. Countries that did exit from currency boards did so mainly for political, rather than economic reasons, and such exits were usually uneventful. Second, modern currency boards have often been instituted to gain credibility following a period of high or hyperinflation, and in this regard, have been remarkably successful. Countries with currency boards experienced lower inflation and higher (if more volatile) GDP growth compared to both floating regimes and simple pegs. The inflation difference reflects both a lower growth rate of money supply (a 'discipline effect'), and a faster growth of money demand (a 'credibility effect'). The GDP growth effect is significant, but may simply reflect a rebound from depressed levels. Third, case studies reveal the successful introduction of a currency board to be far from trivial, requiring lengthy legal and institutional changes, as well as a broad economic and social consensus for the implied commitment. Moreover, there are thorny issues, as yet untested, regarding possible exits from a currency board. Thus currency boards do not provide easy solutions. But if introduced in the right circumstances, with some built-in flexibility, they can be an important tool for gaining credibility and achieving macroeconomic stabilization.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0266-4658</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1468-0327</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1111/1468-0327.00063</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Oxford, UK and Boston, USA: Blackwell Publishers Ltd</publisher><subject>Bank liquidity ; Bank loans ; Banking crises ; Central banks ; Currencies ; Currency ; Currency board ; Economic growth rate ; Economic policy ; Inflation rates ; Monetary policy ; Money ; Policy making ; Studies</subject><ispartof>Economic policy, 2000-10, Vol.15 (31), p.269-335</ispartof><rights>Copyright 2000 Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Economic Studies, Maison des Sciences de l'Homme</rights><rights>Copyright Blackwell Publishers Oct 2000</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c387t-876a9f7c5139d2817122bcd1858e56ba14277182c982f2821007b7835f8352903</citedby></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/1344698$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/1344698$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,780,784,803,27864,27922,27923,58015,58248</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Ghosh, Atish R.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Gulde, Anne-Marie</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Wolf, Holger C.</creatorcontrib><title>Currency boards: More than a quick fix?</title><title>Economic policy</title><description>Once a popular colonial monetary arrangement, currency boards fell into disuse as countries gained political independence. But recently, currency boards have made a remarkable come-back. This essay takes a critical look at their performance. Are currency boards really a panacea for achieving low inflation and high growth? Or do they merely provide a 'quick fix' allowing authorities to neglect fundamental reforms and thus fail to yield lasting benefits? We have three major findings. First, the historical track record of currency boards is sterling, with few instances of speculative attacks and virtually no 'involuntary' exits. Countries that did exit from currency boards did so mainly for political, rather than economic reasons, and such exits were usually uneventful. Second, modern currency boards have often been instituted to gain credibility following a period of high or hyperinflation, and in this regard, have been remarkably successful. Countries with currency boards experienced lower inflation and higher (if more volatile) GDP growth compared to both floating regimes and simple pegs. The inflation difference reflects both a lower growth rate of money supply (a 'discipline effect'), and a faster growth of money demand (a 'credibility effect'). The GDP growth effect is significant, but may simply reflect a rebound from depressed levels. Third, case studies reveal the successful introduction of a currency board to be far from trivial, requiring lengthy legal and institutional changes, as well as a broad economic and social consensus for the implied commitment. Moreover, there are thorny issues, as yet untested, regarding possible exits from a currency board. Thus currency boards do not provide easy solutions. But if introduced in the right circumstances, with some built-in flexibility, they can be an important tool for gaining credibility and achieving macroeconomic stabilization.</description><subject>Bank liquidity</subject><subject>Bank loans</subject><subject>Banking crises</subject><subject>Central banks</subject><subject>Currencies</subject><subject>Currency</subject><subject>Currency board</subject><subject>Economic growth rate</subject><subject>Economic policy</subject><subject>Inflation rates</subject><subject>Monetary policy</subject><subject>Money</subject><subject>Policy making</subject><subject>Studies</subject><issn>0266-4658</issn><issn>1468-0327</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2000</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>7TQ</sourceid><recordid>eNpFkNFLwzAQxoMoWKfPvvhQfPGpWy5pk9QXkapT2CaIom8hTVNsp-uWtLD996ZW5sFxcN_vvuMOoXPAY_AxgZiJCFPCxxhjRg9QsO8cogATxqKYJeIYnThX9wjENEBXWWetWeldmDfKFu46nDfWhO2nWoUq3HSVXoZltb05RUel-nLm7K-O0NvD_Wv2GM2ep0_Z7SzSVPA2EpyptOQ6AZoWRAAHQnJdgEiESViuICacgyA6FaQkggDGPOeCJqVPkmI6QpeD79o2m864VtZNZ1d-pYTUE4wA99BkgLRtnLOmlGtbfSu7k4Bl_wzZny770-XvM_zExTBRu7ax_ziNY5YKL0eDXLnWbPeyskvJOOWJfF9MJXzczV8WDLzvD2ujZVA</recordid><startdate>20001001</startdate><enddate>20001001</enddate><creator>Ghosh, Atish R.</creator><creator>Gulde, Anne-Marie</creator><creator>Wolf, Holger C.</creator><general>Blackwell Publishers Ltd</general><general>Blackwell Publishing</general><general>Oxford University Press</general><scope>BSCLL</scope><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>7TQ</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>DHY</scope><scope>DON</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope></search><sort><creationdate>20001001</creationdate><title>Currency boards: More than a quick fix?</title><author>Ghosh, Atish R. ; Gulde, Anne-Marie ; Wolf, Holger C.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c387t-876a9f7c5139d2817122bcd1858e56ba14277182c982f2821007b7835f8352903</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2000</creationdate><topic>Bank liquidity</topic><topic>Bank loans</topic><topic>Banking crises</topic><topic>Central banks</topic><topic>Currencies</topic><topic>Currency</topic><topic>Currency board</topic><topic>Economic growth rate</topic><topic>Economic policy</topic><topic>Inflation rates</topic><topic>Monetary policy</topic><topic>Money</topic><topic>Policy making</topic><topic>Studies</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Ghosh, Atish R.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Gulde, Anne-Marie</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Wolf, Holger C.</creatorcontrib><collection>Istex</collection><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>PAIS Index</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>PAIS International</collection><collection>PAIS International (Ovid)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><jtitle>Economic policy</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Ghosh, Atish R.</au><au>Gulde, Anne-Marie</au><au>Wolf, Holger C.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Currency boards: More than a quick fix?</atitle><jtitle>Economic policy</jtitle><date>2000-10-01</date><risdate>2000</risdate><volume>15</volume><issue>31</issue><spage>269</spage><epage>335</epage><pages>269-335</pages><issn>0266-4658</issn><eissn>1468-0327</eissn><abstract>Once a popular colonial monetary arrangement, currency boards fell into disuse as countries gained political independence. But recently, currency boards have made a remarkable come-back. This essay takes a critical look at their performance. Are currency boards really a panacea for achieving low inflation and high growth? Or do they merely provide a 'quick fix' allowing authorities to neglect fundamental reforms and thus fail to yield lasting benefits? We have three major findings. First, the historical track record of currency boards is sterling, with few instances of speculative attacks and virtually no 'involuntary' exits. Countries that did exit from currency boards did so mainly for political, rather than economic reasons, and such exits were usually uneventful. Second, modern currency boards have often been instituted to gain credibility following a period of high or hyperinflation, and in this regard, have been remarkably successful. Countries with currency boards experienced lower inflation and higher (if more volatile) GDP growth compared to both floating regimes and simple pegs. The inflation difference reflects both a lower growth rate of money supply (a 'discipline effect'), and a faster growth of money demand (a 'credibility effect'). The GDP growth effect is significant, but may simply reflect a rebound from depressed levels. Third, case studies reveal the successful introduction of a currency board to be far from trivial, requiring lengthy legal and institutional changes, as well as a broad economic and social consensus for the implied commitment. Moreover, there are thorny issues, as yet untested, regarding possible exits from a currency board. Thus currency boards do not provide easy solutions. But if introduced in the right circumstances, with some built-in flexibility, they can be an important tool for gaining credibility and achieving macroeconomic stabilization.</abstract><cop>Oxford, UK and Boston, USA</cop><pub>Blackwell Publishers Ltd</pub><doi>10.1111/1468-0327.00063</doi><tpages>67</tpages></addata></record>
fulltext fulltext
identifier ISSN: 0266-4658
ispartof Economic policy, 2000-10, Vol.15 (31), p.269-335
issn 0266-4658
1468-0327
language eng
recordid cdi_proquest_journals_195296217
source PAIS Index; EBSCOhost Business Source Complete; JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing; Oxford University Press Journals All Titles (1996-Current)
subjects Bank liquidity
Bank loans
Banking crises
Central banks
Currencies
Currency
Currency board
Economic growth rate
Economic policy
Inflation rates
Monetary policy
Money
Policy making
Studies
title Currency boards: More than a quick fix?
url https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-14T01%3A05%3A33IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-jstor_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Currency%20boards:%20More%20than%20a%20quick%20fix?&rft.jtitle=Economic%20policy&rft.au=Ghosh,%20Atish%20R.&rft.date=2000-10-01&rft.volume=15&rft.issue=31&rft.spage=269&rft.epage=335&rft.pages=269-335&rft.issn=0266-4658&rft.eissn=1468-0327&rft_id=info:doi/10.1111/1468-0327.00063&rft_dat=%3Cjstor_proqu%3E1344698%3C/jstor_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=195296217&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_jstor_id=1344698&rfr_iscdi=true