A compact model of oil supply disruptions

We have developed a model of oil price jumps caused by oil supply disruptions. The core of the model is a compact general equilibrium model of oil demand. Given an exogenous forecast of oil supply and potential GNP for the world, the model can forecast the oil price, real GNP, and value added for th...

Ausführliche Beschreibung

Gespeichert in:
Bibliographische Detailangaben
Veröffentlicht in:Resource and energy economics 1988-06, Vol.10 (2), p.161-183
1. Verfasser: Reister, David B.
Format: Artikel
Sprache:eng
Schlagworte:
Online-Zugang:Volltext
Tags: Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
container_end_page 183
container_issue 2
container_start_page 161
container_title Resource and energy economics
container_volume 10
creator Reister, David B.
description We have developed a model of oil price jumps caused by oil supply disruptions. The core of the model is a compact general equilibrium model of oil demand. Given an exogenous forecast of oil supply and potential GNP for the world, the model can forecast the oil price, real GNP, and value added for the world. The data base for the model consists of historical time series of world oil supply, world oil price, and growth rates for world GNP. The data demonstrate that small changes in oil supply are associated with large changes in oil price. If a large change in oil price causes a small change in oil consumption, the short-run price elasticity of demand must be small. We have specified a model with a short-run and a long-run price elasticity. The six parameters in the model have been estimated using historical data for three cases. The initial model had five parameters. For Case 1, we used a search procedure to determine the parameters that minimized the root mean square (RMS) of the differences between the price backcast by the model and the historical data on oil price. We found that the RMS error was 121% and that the price calculated by the model was too low for the period from 1974 to 1980. After a review of the historical data on oil consumption, oil price, and world GNP, we concluded that the response of the world oil market to the 1974 oil price shock was different than the response to the 1979-80 oil price shock. After the jump in oil price from 1973 to 1974, the consumption of oil decreased in 1975 but quickly recovered and reached a peak in 1979. After the jump in oil price from 1978 to 1980, the consumption of oil declined steadily for four consecutive years. To improve the model's capacity to simulate the historical data, we introduced a technological change factor that increases the demand for oil in the period from 1971 to 1979. For Case 2, the rate of technological change is 3.8% and the RMS error is 35%. For Case 3, the rate of technological change is 7.0% and the RMS error is 29%. Although Case 3 has the smallest error, we concluded that the Case 2 set of parameters provided the best match for the historical data on world oil price. For Case 2, we find a small short-run elasticity ( − 0.09), a substantial long-run elasticity ( − 0.92), and a lag of 0.08, which corresponds to 12 years. We have invented an oil price scenario that is similar to the historical data and have determined the corresponding oil supply scenario for the Case 2 set of pa
doi_str_mv 10.1016/0165-0572(88)90018-7
format Article
fullrecord <record><control><sourceid>proquest_cross</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_journals_1839869803</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><els_id>0165057288900187</els_id><sourcerecordid>1292516</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c563t-27da8b42a7237295834ae5c0c05a0a63b49666a6b731252bea3067982f4e61073</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNp9kE1rGzEYhEVpoK6Tf5DD0vYQHzZ5Je3q41IwJp8EcmnPQta-myisV1tpbfC_jzYOvjWHQULMjIaHkHMKlxSouMqqS6glu1BqoQGoKuUXMqNK8hIYo1_J7Gj5Rr6n9ArAgLNqRhbLwoXNYN1YbEKDXRHaIviuSNth6PZF41PcDqMPfTolJ63tEp59nHPy9-b6z-qufHy6vV8tH0tXCz6WTDZWrStmJeOS6VrxymLtwEFtwQq-rrQQwoq15JTVbI2Wg5BasbZCQUHyOflx6B1i-LfFNJrXsI19_tJQrbjgFaXZ9PO_JsW1EloBz67q4HIxpBSxNUP0Gxv3hoKZyJkJi5mwGKXMOzkzLXg4xCIO6I4ZRIyYsH82O8NtbuB2P110jnLrs1jWMD0JOs0wL-Mml_36WGqTs10bbe98OpZK0BXL4Obk98GGGe3OYzTJeewdNj6iG00T_Oej3wAtC5af</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1839869803</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>A compact model of oil supply disruptions</title><source>RePEc</source><source>Periodicals Index Online</source><source>Alma/SFX Local Collection</source><creator>Reister, David B.</creator><creatorcontrib>Reister, David B.</creatorcontrib><description>We have developed a model of oil price jumps caused by oil supply disruptions. The core of the model is a compact general equilibrium model of oil demand. Given an exogenous forecast of oil supply and potential GNP for the world, the model can forecast the oil price, real GNP, and value added for the world. The data base for the model consists of historical time series of world oil supply, world oil price, and growth rates for world GNP. The data demonstrate that small changes in oil supply are associated with large changes in oil price. If a large change in oil price causes a small change in oil consumption, the short-run price elasticity of demand must be small. We have specified a model with a short-run and a long-run price elasticity. The six parameters in the model have been estimated using historical data for three cases. The initial model had five parameters. For Case 1, we used a search procedure to determine the parameters that minimized the root mean square (RMS) of the differences between the price backcast by the model and the historical data on oil price. We found that the RMS error was 121% and that the price calculated by the model was too low for the period from 1974 to 1980. After a review of the historical data on oil consumption, oil price, and world GNP, we concluded that the response of the world oil market to the 1974 oil price shock was different than the response to the 1979-80 oil price shock. After the jump in oil price from 1973 to 1974, the consumption of oil decreased in 1975 but quickly recovered and reached a peak in 1979. After the jump in oil price from 1978 to 1980, the consumption of oil declined steadily for four consecutive years. To improve the model's capacity to simulate the historical data, we introduced a technological change factor that increases the demand for oil in the period from 1971 to 1979. For Case 2, the rate of technological change is 3.8% and the RMS error is 35%. For Case 3, the rate of technological change is 7.0% and the RMS error is 29%. Although Case 3 has the smallest error, we concluded that the Case 2 set of parameters provided the best match for the historical data on world oil price. For Case 2, we find a small short-run elasticity ( − 0.09), a substantial long-run elasticity ( − 0.92), and a lag of 0.08, which corresponds to 12 years. We have invented an oil price scenario that is similar to the historical data and have determined the corresponding oil supply scenario for the Case 2 set of parameters. We have investigated the impact of an increase or decrease of five million barrels per day in 1998.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0165-0572</identifier><identifier>ISSN: 0928-7655</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1873-0221</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1016/0165-0572(88)90018-7</identifier><identifier>CODEN: RESND9</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Amsterdam: Elsevier B.V</publisher><subject>Applied sciences ; Demand ; Economic models ; Energy ; Energy economics ; Exact sciences and technology ; General, economic and professional studies ; GNP ; Gross National Product ; Mathematical models ; Methodology. Modelling ; Oil ; Oil consumption ; Price elasticity ; Simulation ; Time series</subject><ispartof>Resource and energy economics, 1988-06, Vol.10 (2), p.161-183</ispartof><rights>1988</rights><rights>1989 INIST-CNRS</rights><rights>Copyright Elsevier Sequoia S.A. Jun 1988</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><oa>free_for_read</oa><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c563t-27da8b42a7237295834ae5c0c05a0a63b49666a6b731252bea3067982f4e61073</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c563t-27da8b42a7237295834ae5c0c05a0a63b49666a6b731252bea3067982f4e61073</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><link.rule.ids>314,776,780,3993,27848,27903,27904</link.rule.ids><backlink>$$Uhttp://pascal-francis.inist.fr/vibad/index.php?action=getRecordDetail&amp;idt=7094256$$DView record in Pascal Francis$$Hfree_for_read</backlink><backlink>$$Uhttp://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeereseng/v_3a10_3ay_3a1988_3ai_3a2_3ap_3a161-183.htm$$DView record in RePEc$$Hfree_for_read</backlink></links><search><creatorcontrib>Reister, David B.</creatorcontrib><title>A compact model of oil supply disruptions</title><title>Resource and energy economics</title><description>We have developed a model of oil price jumps caused by oil supply disruptions. The core of the model is a compact general equilibrium model of oil demand. Given an exogenous forecast of oil supply and potential GNP for the world, the model can forecast the oil price, real GNP, and value added for the world. The data base for the model consists of historical time series of world oil supply, world oil price, and growth rates for world GNP. The data demonstrate that small changes in oil supply are associated with large changes in oil price. If a large change in oil price causes a small change in oil consumption, the short-run price elasticity of demand must be small. We have specified a model with a short-run and a long-run price elasticity. The six parameters in the model have been estimated using historical data for three cases. The initial model had five parameters. For Case 1, we used a search procedure to determine the parameters that minimized the root mean square (RMS) of the differences between the price backcast by the model and the historical data on oil price. We found that the RMS error was 121% and that the price calculated by the model was too low for the period from 1974 to 1980. After a review of the historical data on oil consumption, oil price, and world GNP, we concluded that the response of the world oil market to the 1974 oil price shock was different than the response to the 1979-80 oil price shock. After the jump in oil price from 1973 to 1974, the consumption of oil decreased in 1975 but quickly recovered and reached a peak in 1979. After the jump in oil price from 1978 to 1980, the consumption of oil declined steadily for four consecutive years. To improve the model's capacity to simulate the historical data, we introduced a technological change factor that increases the demand for oil in the period from 1971 to 1979. For Case 2, the rate of technological change is 3.8% and the RMS error is 35%. For Case 3, the rate of technological change is 7.0% and the RMS error is 29%. Although Case 3 has the smallest error, we concluded that the Case 2 set of parameters provided the best match for the historical data on world oil price. For Case 2, we find a small short-run elasticity ( − 0.09), a substantial long-run elasticity ( − 0.92), and a lag of 0.08, which corresponds to 12 years. We have invented an oil price scenario that is similar to the historical data and have determined the corresponding oil supply scenario for the Case 2 set of parameters. We have investigated the impact of an increase or decrease of five million barrels per day in 1998.</description><subject>Applied sciences</subject><subject>Demand</subject><subject>Economic models</subject><subject>Energy</subject><subject>Energy economics</subject><subject>Exact sciences and technology</subject><subject>General, economic and professional studies</subject><subject>GNP</subject><subject>Gross National Product</subject><subject>Mathematical models</subject><subject>Methodology. Modelling</subject><subject>Oil</subject><subject>Oil consumption</subject><subject>Price elasticity</subject><subject>Simulation</subject><subject>Time series</subject><issn>0165-0572</issn><issn>0928-7655</issn><issn>1873-0221</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>1988</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>X2L</sourceid><sourceid>K30</sourceid><recordid>eNp9kE1rGzEYhEVpoK6Tf5DD0vYQHzZ5Je3q41IwJp8EcmnPQta-myisV1tpbfC_jzYOvjWHQULMjIaHkHMKlxSouMqqS6glu1BqoQGoKuUXMqNK8hIYo1_J7Gj5Rr6n9ArAgLNqRhbLwoXNYN1YbEKDXRHaIviuSNth6PZF41PcDqMPfTolJ63tEp59nHPy9-b6z-qufHy6vV8tH0tXCz6WTDZWrStmJeOS6VrxymLtwEFtwQq-rrQQwoq15JTVbI2Wg5BasbZCQUHyOflx6B1i-LfFNJrXsI19_tJQrbjgFaXZ9PO_JsW1EloBz67q4HIxpBSxNUP0Gxv3hoKZyJkJi5mwGKXMOzkzLXg4xCIO6I4ZRIyYsH82O8NtbuB2P110jnLrs1jWMD0JOs0wL-Mml_36WGqTs10bbe98OpZK0BXL4Obk98GGGe3OYzTJeewdNj6iG00T_Oej3wAtC5af</recordid><startdate>19880601</startdate><enddate>19880601</enddate><creator>Reister, David B.</creator><general>Elsevier B.V</general><general>North-Holland</general><general>Elsevier</general><general>Amsterdam :Elsevier Science Publishers,1993</general><general>Elsevier Sequoia S.A</general><scope>IQODW</scope><scope>DKI</scope><scope>X2L</scope><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>7WH</scope><scope>K30</scope><scope>PAAUG</scope><scope>PAWHS</scope><scope>PAWZZ</scope><scope>PAXOH</scope><scope>PBHAV</scope><scope>PBQSW</scope><scope>PBYQZ</scope><scope>PCIWU</scope><scope>PCMID</scope><scope>PCZJX</scope><scope>PDGRG</scope><scope>PDWWI</scope><scope>PETMR</scope><scope>PFVGT</scope><scope>PGXDX</scope><scope>PIHIL</scope><scope>PISVA</scope><scope>PJCTQ</scope><scope>PJTMS</scope><scope>PLCHJ</scope><scope>PMHAD</scope><scope>PNQDJ</scope><scope>POUND</scope><scope>PPLAD</scope><scope>PQAPC</scope><scope>PQCAN</scope><scope>PQCMW</scope><scope>PQEME</scope><scope>PQHKH</scope><scope>PQMID</scope><scope>PQNCT</scope><scope>PQNET</scope><scope>PQSCT</scope><scope>PQSET</scope><scope>PSVJG</scope><scope>PVMQY</scope><scope>PZGFC</scope><scope>7ST</scope><scope>7TA</scope><scope>8FD</scope><scope>C1K</scope><scope>JG9</scope><scope>SOI</scope></search><sort><creationdate>19880601</creationdate><title>A compact model of oil supply disruptions</title><author>Reister, David B.</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c563t-27da8b42a7237295834ae5c0c05a0a63b49666a6b731252bea3067982f4e61073</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>1988</creationdate><topic>Applied sciences</topic><topic>Demand</topic><topic>Economic models</topic><topic>Energy</topic><topic>Energy economics</topic><topic>Exact sciences and technology</topic><topic>General, economic and professional studies</topic><topic>GNP</topic><topic>Gross National Product</topic><topic>Mathematical models</topic><topic>Methodology. Modelling</topic><topic>Oil</topic><topic>Oil consumption</topic><topic>Price elasticity</topic><topic>Simulation</topic><topic>Time series</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Reister, David B.</creatorcontrib><collection>Pascal-Francis</collection><collection>RePEc IDEAS</collection><collection>RePEc</collection><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 50</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - West</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segments 1-50</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access &amp; Build (Plan A) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - MEA</collection><collection>Environment Abstracts</collection><collection>Materials Business File</collection><collection>Technology Research Database</collection><collection>Environmental Sciences and Pollution Management</collection><collection>Materials Research Database</collection><collection>Environment Abstracts</collection><jtitle>Resource and energy economics</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Reister, David B.</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>A compact model of oil supply disruptions</atitle><jtitle>Resource and energy economics</jtitle><date>1988-06-01</date><risdate>1988</risdate><volume>10</volume><issue>2</issue><spage>161</spage><epage>183</epage><pages>161-183</pages><issn>0165-0572</issn><issn>0928-7655</issn><eissn>1873-0221</eissn><coden>RESND9</coden><abstract>We have developed a model of oil price jumps caused by oil supply disruptions. The core of the model is a compact general equilibrium model of oil demand. Given an exogenous forecast of oil supply and potential GNP for the world, the model can forecast the oil price, real GNP, and value added for the world. The data base for the model consists of historical time series of world oil supply, world oil price, and growth rates for world GNP. The data demonstrate that small changes in oil supply are associated with large changes in oil price. If a large change in oil price causes a small change in oil consumption, the short-run price elasticity of demand must be small. We have specified a model with a short-run and a long-run price elasticity. The six parameters in the model have been estimated using historical data for three cases. The initial model had five parameters. For Case 1, we used a search procedure to determine the parameters that minimized the root mean square (RMS) of the differences between the price backcast by the model and the historical data on oil price. We found that the RMS error was 121% and that the price calculated by the model was too low for the period from 1974 to 1980. After a review of the historical data on oil consumption, oil price, and world GNP, we concluded that the response of the world oil market to the 1974 oil price shock was different than the response to the 1979-80 oil price shock. After the jump in oil price from 1973 to 1974, the consumption of oil decreased in 1975 but quickly recovered and reached a peak in 1979. After the jump in oil price from 1978 to 1980, the consumption of oil declined steadily for four consecutive years. To improve the model's capacity to simulate the historical data, we introduced a technological change factor that increases the demand for oil in the period from 1971 to 1979. For Case 2, the rate of technological change is 3.8% and the RMS error is 35%. For Case 3, the rate of technological change is 7.0% and the RMS error is 29%. Although Case 3 has the smallest error, we concluded that the Case 2 set of parameters provided the best match for the historical data on world oil price. For Case 2, we find a small short-run elasticity ( − 0.09), a substantial long-run elasticity ( − 0.92), and a lag of 0.08, which corresponds to 12 years. We have invented an oil price scenario that is similar to the historical data and have determined the corresponding oil supply scenario for the Case 2 set of parameters. We have investigated the impact of an increase or decrease of five million barrels per day in 1998.</abstract><cop>Amsterdam</cop><pub>Elsevier B.V</pub><doi>10.1016/0165-0572(88)90018-7</doi><tpages>23</tpages><oa>free_for_read</oa></addata></record>
fulltext fulltext
identifier ISSN: 0165-0572
ispartof Resource and energy economics, 1988-06, Vol.10 (2), p.161-183
issn 0165-0572
0928-7655
1873-0221
language eng
recordid cdi_proquest_journals_1839869803
source RePEc; Periodicals Index Online; Alma/SFX Local Collection
subjects Applied sciences
Demand
Economic models
Energy
Energy economics
Exact sciences and technology
General, economic and professional studies
GNP
Gross National Product
Mathematical models
Methodology. Modelling
Oil
Oil consumption
Price elasticity
Simulation
Time series
title A compact model of oil supply disruptions
url https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-01-25T17%3A00%3A37IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-proquest_cross&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=A%20compact%20model%20of%20oil%20supply%20disruptions&rft.jtitle=Resource%20and%20energy%20economics&rft.au=Reister,%20David%20B.&rft.date=1988-06-01&rft.volume=10&rft.issue=2&rft.spage=161&rft.epage=183&rft.pages=161-183&rft.issn=0165-0572&rft.eissn=1873-0221&rft.coden=RESND9&rft_id=info:doi/10.1016/0165-0572(88)90018-7&rft_dat=%3Cproquest_cross%3E1292516%3C/proquest_cross%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1839869803&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_els_id=0165057288900187&rfr_iscdi=true