NORMS MAKE PREFERENCES SOCIAL
We explore the idea that prosocial behavior in experimental games is driven by social norms imported into the laboratory. Under this view, differences in behavior across subjects is driven by heterogeneity in sensitivity to social norms. We introduce an incentivized method of eliciting individual no...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Journal of the European Economic Association 2016-06, Vol.14 (3), p.608-638 |
---|---|
Hauptverfasser: | , |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 638 |
---|---|
container_issue | 3 |
container_start_page | 608 |
container_title | Journal of the European Economic Association |
container_volume | 14 |
creator | Kimbrough, Erik O. Vostroknutov, Alexander |
description | We explore the idea that prosocial behavior in experimental games is driven by social norms imported into the laboratory. Under this view, differences in behavior across subjects is driven by heterogeneity in sensitivity to social norms. We introduce an incentivized method of eliciting individual normsensitivity, and we show how it relates to play in public goods, trust, dictator, and ultimatum games.We show how our observations can be rationalized in a stylized model of norm-dependent preferences under reasonable assumptions about the nature of social norms. Then we directly elicit norms in these games to test the robustness of our interpretation. |
doi_str_mv | 10.1111/jeea.12152 |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>jstor_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_journals_1790521707</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><jstor_id>43965319</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>43965319</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c4302-8f14c502e8da86c54b248ae9b4b34d27adcecd3e02bfc0e2bc163c2f7710b5a13</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNp9jz1PwzAQhi0EEqWwsFeqxIaU4jvbcTJGkQuFfqAWZstxHKlRIWC3Qv33pAQ6cst7w_Pe6SHkGugI2rmrnTMjQBB4QnogOEZcSn563OP4nFyEUFOKFFPZI4P5YjlbDWfZkxo-L9VYLdU8V6vhapFPsuklOavMJrir3-yT17F6yR-i6eJ-kmfTyHJGMUoq4FZQdElpktgKXiBPjEsLXjBeojSldbZkjmJRWeqwsBAzi5WUQAthgPXJTXf3wzefOxe2um52_r19qUGmVCBIKlvqtqOsb0LwrtIffv1m_F4D1Qd9fdDXP_otDB38td64_T-kflQq--sMuk4dto0_djhLY8EgZd_lLmGT</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1790521707</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>NORMS MAKE PREFERENCES SOCIAL</title><source>Jstor Complete Legacy</source><source>Oxford Journals Online</source><source>Business Source Complete</source><creator>Kimbrough, Erik O. ; Vostroknutov, Alexander</creator><creatorcontrib>Kimbrough, Erik O. ; Vostroknutov, Alexander</creatorcontrib><description>We explore the idea that prosocial behavior in experimental games is driven by social norms imported into the laboratory. Under this view, differences in behavior across subjects is driven by heterogeneity in sensitivity to social norms. We introduce an incentivized method of eliciting individual normsensitivity, and we show how it relates to play in public goods, trust, dictator, and ultimatum games.We show how our observations can be rationalized in a stylized model of norm-dependent preferences under reasonable assumptions about the nature of social norms. Then we directly elicit norms in these games to test the robustness of our interpretation.</description><identifier>ISSN: 1542-4766</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1542-4774</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.1111/jeea.12152</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Oxford: Wiley Blackwell for the European Economic Association (EEA)</publisher><subject>C91 ; C92 ; D03 ; Economic models ; Game theory ; Norms ; Social norms</subject><ispartof>Journal of the European Economic Association, 2016-06, Vol.14 (3), p.608-638</ispartof><rights>2016 European Economic Association</rights><rights>2015 by the European Economic Association</rights><rights>2016 by the European Economic Association</rights><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><oa>free_for_read</oa><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed><citedby>FETCH-LOGICAL-c4302-8f14c502e8da86c54b248ae9b4b34d27adcecd3e02bfc0e2bc163c2f7710b5a13</citedby><cites>FETCH-LOGICAL-c4302-8f14c502e8da86c54b248ae9b4b34d27adcecd3e02bfc0e2bc163c2f7710b5a13</cites></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/43965319$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/43965319$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,776,780,799,27901,27902,57992,58225</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Kimbrough, Erik O.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Vostroknutov, Alexander</creatorcontrib><title>NORMS MAKE PREFERENCES SOCIAL</title><title>Journal of the European Economic Association</title><description>We explore the idea that prosocial behavior in experimental games is driven by social norms imported into the laboratory. Under this view, differences in behavior across subjects is driven by heterogeneity in sensitivity to social norms. We introduce an incentivized method of eliciting individual normsensitivity, and we show how it relates to play in public goods, trust, dictator, and ultimatum games.We show how our observations can be rationalized in a stylized model of norm-dependent preferences under reasonable assumptions about the nature of social norms. Then we directly elicit norms in these games to test the robustness of our interpretation.</description><subject>C91</subject><subject>C92</subject><subject>D03</subject><subject>Economic models</subject><subject>Game theory</subject><subject>Norms</subject><subject>Social norms</subject><issn>1542-4766</issn><issn>1542-4774</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2016</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><recordid>eNp9jz1PwzAQhi0EEqWwsFeqxIaU4jvbcTJGkQuFfqAWZstxHKlRIWC3Qv33pAQ6cst7w_Pe6SHkGugI2rmrnTMjQBB4QnogOEZcSn563OP4nFyEUFOKFFPZI4P5YjlbDWfZkxo-L9VYLdU8V6vhapFPsuklOavMJrir3-yT17F6yR-i6eJ-kmfTyHJGMUoq4FZQdElpktgKXiBPjEsLXjBeojSldbZkjmJRWeqwsBAzi5WUQAthgPXJTXf3wzefOxe2um52_r19qUGmVCBIKlvqtqOsb0LwrtIffv1m_F4D1Qd9fdDXP_otDB38td64_T-kflQq--sMuk4dto0_djhLY8EgZd_lLmGT</recordid><startdate>201606</startdate><enddate>201606</enddate><creator>Kimbrough, Erik O.</creator><creator>Vostroknutov, Alexander</creator><general>Wiley Blackwell for the European Economic Association (EEA)</general><general>Oxford University Press</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope></search><sort><creationdate>201606</creationdate><title>NORMS MAKE PREFERENCES SOCIAL</title><author>Kimbrough, Erik O. ; Vostroknutov, Alexander</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c4302-8f14c502e8da86c54b248ae9b4b34d27adcecd3e02bfc0e2bc163c2f7710b5a13</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2016</creationdate><topic>C91</topic><topic>C92</topic><topic>D03</topic><topic>Economic models</topic><topic>Game theory</topic><topic>Norms</topic><topic>Social norms</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Kimbrough, Erik O.</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Vostroknutov, Alexander</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><jtitle>Journal of the European Economic Association</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Kimbrough, Erik O.</au><au>Vostroknutov, Alexander</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>NORMS MAKE PREFERENCES SOCIAL</atitle><jtitle>Journal of the European Economic Association</jtitle><date>2016-06</date><risdate>2016</risdate><volume>14</volume><issue>3</issue><spage>608</spage><epage>638</epage><pages>608-638</pages><issn>1542-4766</issn><eissn>1542-4774</eissn><abstract>We explore the idea that prosocial behavior in experimental games is driven by social norms imported into the laboratory. Under this view, differences in behavior across subjects is driven by heterogeneity in sensitivity to social norms. We introduce an incentivized method of eliciting individual normsensitivity, and we show how it relates to play in public goods, trust, dictator, and ultimatum games.We show how our observations can be rationalized in a stylized model of norm-dependent preferences under reasonable assumptions about the nature of social norms. Then we directly elicit norms in these games to test the robustness of our interpretation.</abstract><cop>Oxford</cop><pub>Wiley Blackwell for the European Economic Association (EEA)</pub><doi>10.1111/jeea.12152</doi><tpages>31</tpages><oa>free_for_read</oa></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 1542-4766 |
ispartof | Journal of the European Economic Association, 2016-06, Vol.14 (3), p.608-638 |
issn | 1542-4766 1542-4774 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_journals_1790521707 |
source | Jstor Complete Legacy; Oxford Journals Online; Business Source Complete |
subjects | C91 C92 D03 Economic models Game theory Norms Social norms |
title | NORMS MAKE PREFERENCES SOCIAL |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2025-02-12T00%3A07%3A50IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-jstor_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=NORMS%20MAKE%20PREFERENCES%20SOCIAL&rft.jtitle=Journal%20of%20the%20European%20Economic%20Association&rft.au=Kimbrough,%20Erik%20O.&rft.date=2016-06&rft.volume=14&rft.issue=3&rft.spage=608&rft.epage=638&rft.pages=608-638&rft.issn=1542-4766&rft.eissn=1542-4774&rft_id=info:doi/10.1111/jeea.12152&rft_dat=%3Cjstor_proqu%3E43965319%3C/jstor_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1790521707&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_jstor_id=43965319&rfr_iscdi=true |