Liberalization and Unorganized Money Markets
An intertemporal optimizing model is used to study the welfare consequences of sequential liberalization programs in an environment where financial intermediation occurs not only in official money markets but also in unofficial(curb or grey money) markets. It is shown that raising the regulated offi...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | Journal of International Economic Integration 1990-10, Vol.5 (2), p.57-71 |
---|---|
Hauptverfasser: | , |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 71 |
---|---|
container_issue | 2 |
container_start_page | 57 |
container_title | Journal of International Economic Integration |
container_volume | 5 |
creator | Haaparanta, Pertti Kähkönen, Juha |
description | An intertemporal optimizing model is used to study the welfare consequences of sequential liberalization programs in an environment where financial intermediation occurs not only in official money markets but also in unofficial(curb or grey money) markets. It is shown that raising the regulated official interest rate, which is often recommended in the financial repression literature as a measure to mobilize savings, can be welfare reducing if either trade is restricted or the fall in the unofficial interest rate caused by the reform has a very large effect on investment and future income. Similar nonstandard conclusions are shown to hold for other types of partial reforms. |
doi_str_mv | 10.11130/jei.1990.5.2.57 |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>jstor_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_proquest_journals_1309265240</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><jstor_id>23000077</jstor_id><sourcerecordid>23000077</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-c1647-aabbdac0d6db56a68f61906a1226146c5e473b953783a5350fba8218f3ec67e43</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNo9kE1Lw0AQhhdRsNTevQgBrybuR2Y2OUrRKrR4seBtmSQbSazZupse2l_v1opzmTk87wzzMHYteCaEUPy-t10mypJnkMkM9BmbiFJjCiDhPM5cQKoA3y_ZLISex0Kuciwm7G7ZVdbTpjvQ2LkhoaFJ1oPzHzR0B9skKzfYfbIi_2nHcMUuWtoEO_vrU7Z-enybP6fL18XL_GGZ1gJznRJVVUM1b7CpAAmLFkXJkYSUKHKsweZaVSUoXSgCBbytqJCiaJWtUdtcTdntae_Wu--dDaPp3c4P8aSJz5YSQeY8UvxE1d6F4G1rtr77Ir83gptfLSZqMUctBow0oGPk5hTpw-j8Py_VUYnW6gfkzF3G</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>1309265240</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Liberalization and Unorganized Money Markets</title><source>Periodicals Index Online</source><source>JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing</source><source>EZB-FREE-00999 freely available EZB journals</source><creator>Haaparanta, Pertti ; Kähkönen, Juha</creator><creatorcontrib>Haaparanta, Pertti ; Kähkönen, Juha</creatorcontrib><description>An intertemporal optimizing model is used to study the welfare consequences of sequential liberalization programs in an environment where financial intermediation occurs not only in official money markets but also in unofficial(curb or grey money) markets. It is shown that raising the regulated official interest rate, which is often recommended in the financial repression literature as a measure to mobilize savings, can be welfare reducing if either trade is restricted or the fall in the unofficial interest rate caused by the reform has a very large effect on investment and future income. Similar nonstandard conclusions are shown to hold for other types of partial reforms.</description><identifier>ISSN: 1015-356X</identifier><identifier>ISSN: 1225-651X</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1976-5525</identifier><identifier>DOI: 10.11130/jei.1990.5.2.57</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>Seoul, Korea: Institute for International Economics, King Sejong University</publisher><subject>Bank loans ; Deposit rates ; Financial investments ; International economics ; Liberalization ; Marginal costs ; Repression ; Savings ; Tariffs ; Trade liberalization</subject><ispartof>Journal of International Economic Integration, 1990-10, Vol.5 (2), p.57-71</ispartof><lds50>peer_reviewed</lds50><oa>free_for_read</oa><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><linktopdf>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/23000077$$EPDF$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktopdf><linktohtml>$$Uhttps://www.jstor.org/stable/23000077$$EHTML$$P50$$Gjstor$$H</linktohtml><link.rule.ids>314,780,784,803,27869,27924,27925,58017,58250</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Haaparanta, Pertti</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Kähkönen, Juha</creatorcontrib><title>Liberalization and Unorganized Money Markets</title><title>Journal of International Economic Integration</title><description>An intertemporal optimizing model is used to study the welfare consequences of sequential liberalization programs in an environment where financial intermediation occurs not only in official money markets but also in unofficial(curb or grey money) markets. It is shown that raising the regulated official interest rate, which is often recommended in the financial repression literature as a measure to mobilize savings, can be welfare reducing if either trade is restricted or the fall in the unofficial interest rate caused by the reform has a very large effect on investment and future income. Similar nonstandard conclusions are shown to hold for other types of partial reforms.</description><subject>Bank loans</subject><subject>Deposit rates</subject><subject>Financial investments</subject><subject>International economics</subject><subject>Liberalization</subject><subject>Marginal costs</subject><subject>Repression</subject><subject>Savings</subject><subject>Tariffs</subject><subject>Trade liberalization</subject><issn>1015-356X</issn><issn>1225-651X</issn><issn>1976-5525</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>1990</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>K30</sourceid><recordid>eNo9kE1Lw0AQhhdRsNTevQgBrybuR2Y2OUrRKrR4seBtmSQbSazZupse2l_v1opzmTk87wzzMHYteCaEUPy-t10mypJnkMkM9BmbiFJjCiDhPM5cQKoA3y_ZLISex0Kuciwm7G7ZVdbTpjvQ2LkhoaFJ1oPzHzR0B9skKzfYfbIi_2nHcMUuWtoEO_vrU7Z-enybP6fL18XL_GGZ1gJznRJVVUM1b7CpAAmLFkXJkYSUKHKsweZaVSUoXSgCBbytqJCiaJWtUdtcTdntae_Wu--dDaPp3c4P8aSJz5YSQeY8UvxE1d6F4G1rtr77Ir83gptfLSZqMUctBow0oGPk5hTpw-j8Py_VUYnW6gfkzF3G</recordid><startdate>19901001</startdate><enddate>19901001</enddate><creator>Haaparanta, Pertti</creator><creator>Kähkönen, Juha</creator><general>Institute for International Economics, King Sejong University</general><general>Institute for International Economics, Sejong University</general><scope>AAYXX</scope><scope>CITATION</scope><scope>JXBYG</scope><scope>K30</scope><scope>PAAUG</scope><scope>PAWHS</scope><scope>PAWZZ</scope><scope>PAXOH</scope><scope>PBHAV</scope><scope>PBQSW</scope><scope>PBYQZ</scope><scope>PCIWU</scope><scope>PCMID</scope><scope>PCZJX</scope><scope>PDGRG</scope><scope>PDWWI</scope><scope>PETMR</scope><scope>PFVGT</scope><scope>PGXDX</scope><scope>PIHIL</scope><scope>PISVA</scope><scope>PJCTQ</scope><scope>PJTMS</scope><scope>PLCHJ</scope><scope>PMHAD</scope><scope>PNQDJ</scope><scope>POUND</scope><scope>PPLAD</scope><scope>PQAPC</scope><scope>PQCAN</scope><scope>PQCMW</scope><scope>PQEME</scope><scope>PQHKH</scope><scope>PQMID</scope><scope>PQNCT</scope><scope>PQNET</scope><scope>PQSCT</scope><scope>PQSET</scope><scope>PSVJG</scope><scope>PVMQY</scope><scope>PZGFC</scope><scope>SFNNT</scope></search><sort><creationdate>19901001</creationdate><title>Liberalization and Unorganized Money Markets</title><author>Haaparanta, Pertti ; Kähkönen, Juha</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-c1647-aabbdac0d6db56a68f61906a1226146c5e473b953783a5350fba8218f3ec67e43</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>1990</creationdate><topic>Bank loans</topic><topic>Deposit rates</topic><topic>Financial investments</topic><topic>International economics</topic><topic>Liberalization</topic><topic>Marginal costs</topic><topic>Repression</topic><topic>Savings</topic><topic>Tariffs</topic><topic>Trade liberalization</topic><toplevel>peer_reviewed</toplevel><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Haaparanta, Pertti</creatorcontrib><creatorcontrib>Kähkönen, Juha</creatorcontrib><collection>CrossRef</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 40</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - International</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - West</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segments 1-50</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - MEA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Canada</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - West</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - EMEALA</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Midwest</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - North Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Northeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - South Central</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access & Build (Plan A) - Southeast</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access (Plan D) - UK / I</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - APAC</collection><collection>Primary Sources Access—Foundation Edition (Plan E) - MEA</collection><collection>Periodicals Index Online Segment 44</collection><jtitle>Journal of International Economic Integration</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Haaparanta, Pertti</au><au>Kähkönen, Juha</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Liberalization and Unorganized Money Markets</atitle><jtitle>Journal of International Economic Integration</jtitle><date>1990-10-01</date><risdate>1990</risdate><volume>5</volume><issue>2</issue><spage>57</spage><epage>71</epage><pages>57-71</pages><issn>1015-356X</issn><issn>1225-651X</issn><eissn>1976-5525</eissn><abstract>An intertemporal optimizing model is used to study the welfare consequences of sequential liberalization programs in an environment where financial intermediation occurs not only in official money markets but also in unofficial(curb or grey money) markets. It is shown that raising the regulated official interest rate, which is often recommended in the financial repression literature as a measure to mobilize savings, can be welfare reducing if either trade is restricted or the fall in the unofficial interest rate caused by the reform has a very large effect on investment and future income. Similar nonstandard conclusions are shown to hold for other types of partial reforms.</abstract><cop>Seoul, Korea</cop><pub>Institute for International Economics, King Sejong University</pub><doi>10.11130/jei.1990.5.2.57</doi><tpages>15</tpages><oa>free_for_read</oa></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 1015-356X |
ispartof | Journal of International Economic Integration, 1990-10, Vol.5 (2), p.57-71 |
issn | 1015-356X 1225-651X 1976-5525 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_proquest_journals_1309265240 |
source | Periodicals Index Online; JSTOR Archive Collection A-Z Listing; EZB-FREE-00999 freely available EZB journals |
subjects | Bank loans Deposit rates Financial investments International economics Liberalization Marginal costs Repression Savings Tariffs Trade liberalization |
title | Liberalization and Unorganized Money Markets |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2024-12-23T05%3A37%3A35IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-jstor_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Liberalization%20and%20Unorganized%20Money%20Markets&rft.jtitle=Journal%20of%20International%20Economic%20Integration&rft.au=Haaparanta,%20Pertti&rft.date=1990-10-01&rft.volume=5&rft.issue=2&rft.spage=57&rft.epage=71&rft.pages=57-71&rft.issn=1015-356X&rft.eissn=1976-5525&rft_id=info:doi/10.11130/jei.1990.5.2.57&rft_dat=%3Cjstor_proqu%3E23000077%3C/jstor_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=1309265240&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_jstor_id=23000077&rfr_iscdi=true |