Antitrust and platform monopoly
Contrary to common belief, large digital platforms that deal directly with consumers, such as Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google, are not "winner-take-all" firms. They must compete on the merits or otherwise rely on exclusionary practices to attain or maintain dominance, and this gives an...
Gespeichert in:
Veröffentlicht in: | The Yale law journal 2021-07, Vol.130 (8), p.1952-2050 |
---|---|
1. Verfasser: | |
Format: | Artikel |
Sprache: | eng |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Tags: |
Tag hinzufügen
Keine Tags, Fügen Sie den ersten Tag hinzu!
|
container_end_page | 2050 |
---|---|
container_issue | 8 |
container_start_page | 1952 |
container_title | The Yale law journal |
container_volume | 130 |
creator | Hovenkamp, Herbert |
description | Contrary to common belief, large digital platforms that deal directly with consumers, such as Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google, are not "winner-take-all" firms. They must compete on the merits or otherwise rely on exclusionary practices to attain or maintain dominance, and this gives antitrust policy a role. While regulation may be appropriate in a few areas such as for consumer privacy, antitrust's firm-specific approach is more adept at addressing most threats to platform competition. When platforms exert their market power over other firms, liability may be apt, but remedies present another puzzle. For the several pending antitrust complaints against Google and Facebook, for instance, what should be the remedy if there is a violation? Breaking up large firms that benefit from extensive economies of scale and scope will injure consumers and most input suppliers, including the employees who supply labor. In many situations, a better approach would be to restructure management rather than assets, which would leave the platform intact as a production entity but make decision-making more competitive. A second option to breaking up firms would be to require interoperability - and in the information context, mandate the pooling of valuable information. These measures could promote competition and simultaneously increase the value of positive network effects. Finally, this article examines another aspect of platforms - their acquisitions. For the most salient category of platform acquisitions of nascent firms, the greatest threat to competition comes from platforms' acquisitions of complements or differentiated technologies. Current merger-enforcement tools are ill suited to analyze this new variation on competitive harm. New approaches are required. |
format | Article |
fullrecord | <record><control><sourceid>gale_proqu</sourceid><recordid>TN_cdi_gale_businessinsightsgauss_A672359553</recordid><sourceformat>XML</sourceformat><sourcesystem>PC</sourcesystem><galeid>A672359553</galeid><informt_id>10.3316/agispt.20210716050117</informt_id><sourcerecordid>A672359553</sourcerecordid><originalsourceid>FETCH-LOGICAL-g526t-a4b0850a46ed0940ae9d2b5d68df40b23f97ef1a03db0b8fa4c7e128f188c24f3</originalsourceid><addsrcrecordid>eNqV0E1LwzAYB_AgCs7pZ3DgSbCS174cx1A3GOyiXkPaJF1G29QkBf32hk3R4i4mkEDye_5PyAmYoIIUSZ4idAomEFKaQFjQc3Dh_Q7GQYtiAq7nXTDBDT7MRCdnfSOCtq6dtbazvW0-LsGZFo1XV1_7FLw8Pjwvlsl687RazNdJzXAaEkFLmDMoaKpkbAKFKiQumUxzqSksMdFFpjQSkMgSlrkWtMoUwrlGeV5hqskU3Bxye2ffBuUD39nBdbElx4yxNEcZwT-qFo3iptM2OFG1xld8nmaYsIIxElVyRNWqU040tlPaxOORvz_i45SqNdXRgttRQTRBvYdaDN7z1eZ1bO9-2XLwplM-Lt7U2-APJSO-PnDXmsBFbXwf-DaE3nMpgti_bn9lXc2lNRxBTghKvymGGMEMpZBBFL9sCpZ_47wSrtr-N-oTcl-1qQ</addsrcrecordid><sourcetype>Aggregation Database</sourcetype><iscdi>true</iscdi><recordtype>article</recordtype><pqid>2555681732</pqid></control><display><type>article</type><title>Antitrust and platform monopoly</title><source>HeinOnline Law Journal Library</source><source>Free E- Journals</source><creator>Hovenkamp, Herbert</creator><creatorcontrib>Hovenkamp, Herbert</creatorcontrib><description>Contrary to common belief, large digital platforms that deal directly with consumers, such as Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google, are not "winner-take-all" firms. They must compete on the merits or otherwise rely on exclusionary practices to attain or maintain dominance, and this gives antitrust policy a role. While regulation may be appropriate in a few areas such as for consumer privacy, antitrust's firm-specific approach is more adept at addressing most threats to platform competition. When platforms exert their market power over other firms, liability may be apt, but remedies present another puzzle. For the several pending antitrust complaints against Google and Facebook, for instance, what should be the remedy if there is a violation? Breaking up large firms that benefit from extensive economies of scale and scope will injure consumers and most input suppliers, including the employees who supply labor. In many situations, a better approach would be to restructure management rather than assets, which would leave the platform intact as a production entity but make decision-making more competitive. A second option to breaking up firms would be to require interoperability - and in the information context, mandate the pooling of valuable information. These measures could promote competition and simultaneously increase the value of positive network effects. Finally, this article examines another aspect of platforms - their acquisitions. For the most salient category of platform acquisitions of nascent firms, the greatest threat to competition comes from platforms' acquisitions of complements or differentiated technologies. Current merger-enforcement tools are ill suited to analyze this new variation on competitive harm. New approaches are required.</description><identifier>ISSN: 0044-0094</identifier><identifier>EISSN: 1939-8611</identifier><language>eng</language><publisher>New Haven: Yale University, School of Law</publisher><subject>Acquisition ; Antitrust ; Antitrust law ; Antitrust law (International law) ; Companies ; Competition ; COMPETITION LAW ; Complaints ; Consumers ; Decision making ; Dominance ; Economies of scale ; Enforcement ; Laws, regulations and rules ; Market share ; MONOPOLIES ; Privacy ; Public policy ; REMEDIES ; Remedies (Law) ; SOCIAL MEDIA ; TECHNOLOGY ; Threats ; TRADE PRACTICES ; United States. Federal Trade Commission</subject><ispartof>The Yale law journal, 2021-07, Vol.130 (8), p.1952-2050</ispartof><rights>COPYRIGHT 2021 Yale University, School of Law</rights><rights>Copyright Yale Law Journal Company, Inc. Jun 2021</rights><woscitedreferencessubscribed>false</woscitedreferencessubscribed></display><links><openurl>$$Topenurl_article</openurl><openurlfulltext>$$Topenurlfull_article</openurlfulltext><thumbnail>$$Tsyndetics_thumb_exl</thumbnail><link.rule.ids>314,780,784</link.rule.ids></links><search><creatorcontrib>Hovenkamp, Herbert</creatorcontrib><title>Antitrust and platform monopoly</title><title>The Yale law journal</title><description>Contrary to common belief, large digital platforms that deal directly with consumers, such as Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google, are not "winner-take-all" firms. They must compete on the merits or otherwise rely on exclusionary practices to attain or maintain dominance, and this gives antitrust policy a role. While regulation may be appropriate in a few areas such as for consumer privacy, antitrust's firm-specific approach is more adept at addressing most threats to platform competition. When platforms exert their market power over other firms, liability may be apt, but remedies present another puzzle. For the several pending antitrust complaints against Google and Facebook, for instance, what should be the remedy if there is a violation? Breaking up large firms that benefit from extensive economies of scale and scope will injure consumers and most input suppliers, including the employees who supply labor. In many situations, a better approach would be to restructure management rather than assets, which would leave the platform intact as a production entity but make decision-making more competitive. A second option to breaking up firms would be to require interoperability - and in the information context, mandate the pooling of valuable information. These measures could promote competition and simultaneously increase the value of positive network effects. Finally, this article examines another aspect of platforms - their acquisitions. For the most salient category of platform acquisitions of nascent firms, the greatest threat to competition comes from platforms' acquisitions of complements or differentiated technologies. Current merger-enforcement tools are ill suited to analyze this new variation on competitive harm. New approaches are required.</description><subject>Acquisition</subject><subject>Antitrust</subject><subject>Antitrust law</subject><subject>Antitrust law (International law)</subject><subject>Companies</subject><subject>Competition</subject><subject>COMPETITION LAW</subject><subject>Complaints</subject><subject>Consumers</subject><subject>Decision making</subject><subject>Dominance</subject><subject>Economies of scale</subject><subject>Enforcement</subject><subject>Laws, regulations and rules</subject><subject>Market share</subject><subject>MONOPOLIES</subject><subject>Privacy</subject><subject>Public policy</subject><subject>REMEDIES</subject><subject>Remedies (Law)</subject><subject>SOCIAL MEDIA</subject><subject>TECHNOLOGY</subject><subject>Threats</subject><subject>TRADE PRACTICES</subject><subject>United States. Federal Trade Commission</subject><issn>0044-0094</issn><issn>1939-8611</issn><fulltext>true</fulltext><rsrctype>article</rsrctype><creationdate>2021</creationdate><recordtype>article</recordtype><sourceid>N95</sourceid><recordid>eNqV0E1LwzAYB_AgCs7pZ3DgSbCS174cx1A3GOyiXkPaJF1G29QkBf32hk3R4i4mkEDye_5PyAmYoIIUSZ4idAomEFKaQFjQc3Dh_Q7GQYtiAq7nXTDBDT7MRCdnfSOCtq6dtbazvW0-LsGZFo1XV1_7FLw8Pjwvlsl687RazNdJzXAaEkFLmDMoaKpkbAKFKiQumUxzqSksMdFFpjQSkMgSlrkWtMoUwrlGeV5hqskU3Bxye2ffBuUD39nBdbElx4yxNEcZwT-qFo3iptM2OFG1xld8nmaYsIIxElVyRNWqU040tlPaxOORvz_i45SqNdXRgttRQTRBvYdaDN7z1eZ1bO9-2XLwplM-Lt7U2-APJSO-PnDXmsBFbXwf-DaE3nMpgti_bn9lXc2lNRxBTghKvymGGMEMpZBBFL9sCpZ_47wSrtr-N-oTcl-1qQ</recordid><startdate>20210701</startdate><enddate>20210701</enddate><creator>Hovenkamp, Herbert</creator><general>Yale University, School of Law</general><general>Yale Law Journal Company, Inc</general><scope>N95</scope><scope>XI7</scope><scope>IOV</scope><scope>ILT</scope><scope>8BJ</scope><scope>FQK</scope><scope>JBE</scope></search><sort><creationdate>20210701</creationdate><title>Antitrust and platform monopoly</title><author>Hovenkamp, Herbert</author></sort><facets><frbrtype>5</frbrtype><frbrgroupid>cdi_FETCH-LOGICAL-g526t-a4b0850a46ed0940ae9d2b5d68df40b23f97ef1a03db0b8fa4c7e128f188c24f3</frbrgroupid><rsrctype>articles</rsrctype><prefilter>articles</prefilter><language>eng</language><creationdate>2021</creationdate><topic>Acquisition</topic><topic>Antitrust</topic><topic>Antitrust law</topic><topic>Antitrust law (International law)</topic><topic>Companies</topic><topic>Competition</topic><topic>COMPETITION LAW</topic><topic>Complaints</topic><topic>Consumers</topic><topic>Decision making</topic><topic>Dominance</topic><topic>Economies of scale</topic><topic>Enforcement</topic><topic>Laws, regulations and rules</topic><topic>Market share</topic><topic>MONOPOLIES</topic><topic>Privacy</topic><topic>Public policy</topic><topic>REMEDIES</topic><topic>Remedies (Law)</topic><topic>SOCIAL MEDIA</topic><topic>TECHNOLOGY</topic><topic>Threats</topic><topic>TRADE PRACTICES</topic><topic>United States. Federal Trade Commission</topic><toplevel>online_resources</toplevel><creatorcontrib>Hovenkamp, Herbert</creatorcontrib><collection>Gale Business: Insights</collection><collection>Business Insights: Essentials</collection><collection>Gale In Context: Opposing Viewpoints</collection><collection>Gale OneFile: LegalTrac</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS)</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><collection>International Bibliography of the Social Sciences</collection><jtitle>The Yale law journal</jtitle></facets><delivery><delcategory>Remote Search Resource</delcategory><fulltext>fulltext</fulltext></delivery><addata><au>Hovenkamp, Herbert</au><format>journal</format><genre>article</genre><ristype>JOUR</ristype><atitle>Antitrust and platform monopoly</atitle><jtitle>The Yale law journal</jtitle><date>2021-07-01</date><risdate>2021</risdate><volume>130</volume><issue>8</issue><spage>1952</spage><epage>2050</epage><pages>1952-2050</pages><issn>0044-0094</issn><eissn>1939-8611</eissn><abstract>Contrary to common belief, large digital platforms that deal directly with consumers, such as Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google, are not "winner-take-all" firms. They must compete on the merits or otherwise rely on exclusionary practices to attain or maintain dominance, and this gives antitrust policy a role. While regulation may be appropriate in a few areas such as for consumer privacy, antitrust's firm-specific approach is more adept at addressing most threats to platform competition. When platforms exert their market power over other firms, liability may be apt, but remedies present another puzzle. For the several pending antitrust complaints against Google and Facebook, for instance, what should be the remedy if there is a violation? Breaking up large firms that benefit from extensive economies of scale and scope will injure consumers and most input suppliers, including the employees who supply labor. In many situations, a better approach would be to restructure management rather than assets, which would leave the platform intact as a production entity but make decision-making more competitive. A second option to breaking up firms would be to require interoperability - and in the information context, mandate the pooling of valuable information. These measures could promote competition and simultaneously increase the value of positive network effects. Finally, this article examines another aspect of platforms - their acquisitions. For the most salient category of platform acquisitions of nascent firms, the greatest threat to competition comes from platforms' acquisitions of complements or differentiated technologies. Current merger-enforcement tools are ill suited to analyze this new variation on competitive harm. New approaches are required.</abstract><cop>New Haven</cop><pub>Yale University, School of Law</pub><tpages>99</tpages></addata></record> |
fulltext | fulltext |
identifier | ISSN: 0044-0094 |
ispartof | The Yale law journal, 2021-07, Vol.130 (8), p.1952-2050 |
issn | 0044-0094 1939-8611 |
language | eng |
recordid | cdi_gale_businessinsightsgauss_A672359553 |
source | HeinOnline Law Journal Library; Free E- Journals |
subjects | Acquisition Antitrust Antitrust law Antitrust law (International law) Companies Competition COMPETITION LAW Complaints Consumers Decision making Dominance Economies of scale Enforcement Laws, regulations and rules Market share MONOPOLIES Privacy Public policy REMEDIES Remedies (Law) SOCIAL MEDIA TECHNOLOGY Threats TRADE PRACTICES United States. Federal Trade Commission |
title | Antitrust and platform monopoly |
url | https://sfx.bib-bvb.de/sfx_tum?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2024-12-24T13%3A18%3A35IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-gale_proqu&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:journal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Antitrust%20and%20platform%20monopoly&rft.jtitle=The%20Yale%20law%20journal&rft.au=Hovenkamp,%20Herbert&rft.date=2021-07-01&rft.volume=130&rft.issue=8&rft.spage=1952&rft.epage=2050&rft.pages=1952-2050&rft.issn=0044-0094&rft.eissn=1939-8611&rft_id=info:doi/&rft_dat=%3Cgale_proqu%3EA672359553%3C/gale_proqu%3E%3Curl%3E%3C/url%3E&disable_directlink=true&sfx.directlink=off&sfx.report_link=0&rft_id=info:oai/&rft_pqid=2555681732&rft_id=info:pmid/&rft_galeid=A672359553&rft_informt_id=10.3316/agispt.20210716050117&rfr_iscdi=true |